This website uses cookies.

By clicking the "Accept" button or continuing to browse our site, you agree to first-party and session-only cookies being stored on your device to enhance site navigation and analyze site performance and traffic. For more information on our use of cookies, please see our Privacy Policy .

  • Journal of Economic Literature
  • December 2019

Tax Compliance and Enforcement

  • Joel Slemrod
  • Article Information

Additional Materials

  • Author Disclosure Statement(s) (25.14 KB)

JEL Classification

  • H30 Fiscal Policies and Behavior of Economic Agents: General
  • Search Menu
  • Browse content in Arts and Humanities
  • Browse content in Archaeology
  • Anglo-Saxon and Medieval Archaeology
  • Archaeological Methodology and Techniques
  • Archaeology by Region
  • Archaeology of Religion
  • Archaeology of Trade and Exchange
  • Biblical Archaeology
  • Contemporary and Public Archaeology
  • Environmental Archaeology
  • Historical Archaeology
  • History and Theory of Archaeology
  • Industrial Archaeology
  • Landscape Archaeology
  • Mortuary Archaeology
  • Prehistoric Archaeology
  • Underwater Archaeology
  • Urban Archaeology
  • Zooarchaeology
  • Browse content in Architecture
  • Architectural Structure and Design
  • History of Architecture
  • Residential and Domestic Buildings
  • Theory of Architecture
  • Browse content in Art
  • Art Subjects and Themes
  • History of Art
  • Industrial and Commercial Art
  • Theory of Art
  • Biographical Studies
  • Byzantine Studies
  • Browse content in Classical Studies
  • Classical History
  • Classical Philosophy
  • Classical Mythology
  • Classical Literature
  • Classical Reception
  • Classical Art and Architecture
  • Classical Oratory and Rhetoric
  • Greek and Roman Epigraphy
  • Greek and Roman Law
  • Greek and Roman Archaeology
  • Greek and Roman Papyrology
  • Late Antiquity
  • Religion in the Ancient World
  • Digital Humanities
  • Browse content in History
  • Colonialism and Imperialism
  • Diplomatic History
  • Environmental History
  • Genealogy, Heraldry, Names, and Honours
  • Genocide and Ethnic Cleansing
  • Historical Geography
  • History by Period
  • History of Agriculture
  • History of Education
  • History of Emotions
  • History of Gender and Sexuality
  • Industrial History
  • Intellectual History
  • International History
  • Labour History
  • Legal and Constitutional History
  • Local and Family History
  • Maritime History
  • Military History
  • National Liberation and Post-Colonialism
  • Oral History
  • Political History
  • Public History
  • Regional and National History
  • Revolutions and Rebellions
  • Slavery and Abolition of Slavery
  • Social and Cultural History
  • Theory, Methods, and Historiography
  • Urban History
  • World History
  • Browse content in Language Teaching and Learning
  • Language Learning (Specific Skills)
  • Language Teaching Theory and Methods
  • Browse content in Linguistics
  • Applied Linguistics
  • Cognitive Linguistics
  • Computational Linguistics
  • Forensic Linguistics
  • Grammar, Syntax and Morphology
  • Historical and Diachronic Linguistics
  • History of English
  • Language Acquisition
  • Language Variation
  • Language Families
  • Language Evolution
  • Language Reference
  • Lexicography
  • Linguistic Theories
  • Linguistic Typology
  • Linguistic Anthropology
  • Phonetics and Phonology
  • Psycholinguistics
  • Sociolinguistics
  • Translation and Interpretation
  • Writing Systems
  • Browse content in Literature
  • Bibliography
  • Children's Literature Studies
  • Literary Studies (Asian)
  • Literary Studies (European)
  • Literary Studies (Eco-criticism)
  • Literary Studies (Modernism)
  • Literary Studies (Romanticism)
  • Literary Studies (American)
  • Literary Studies - World
  • Literary Studies (1500 to 1800)
  • Literary Studies (19th Century)
  • Literary Studies (20th Century onwards)
  • Literary Studies (African American Literature)
  • Literary Studies (British and Irish)
  • Literary Studies (Early and Medieval)
  • Literary Studies (Fiction, Novelists, and Prose Writers)
  • Literary Studies (Gender Studies)
  • Literary Studies (Graphic Novels)
  • Literary Studies (History of the Book)
  • Literary Studies (Plays and Playwrights)
  • Literary Studies (Poetry and Poets)
  • Literary Studies (Postcolonial Literature)
  • Literary Studies (Queer Studies)
  • Literary Studies (Science Fiction)
  • Literary Studies (Travel Literature)
  • Literary Studies (War Literature)
  • Literary Studies (Women's Writing)
  • Literary Theory and Cultural Studies
  • Mythology and Folklore
  • Shakespeare Studies and Criticism
  • Browse content in Media Studies
  • Browse content in Music
  • Applied Music
  • Dance and Music
  • Ethics in Music
  • Ethnomusicology
  • Gender and Sexuality in Music
  • Medicine and Music
  • Music Cultures
  • Music and Religion
  • Music and Culture
  • Music and Media
  • Music Education and Pedagogy
  • Music Theory and Analysis
  • Musical Scores, Lyrics, and Libretti
  • Musical Structures, Styles, and Techniques
  • Musicology and Music History
  • Performance Practice and Studies
  • Race and Ethnicity in Music
  • Sound Studies
  • Browse content in Performing Arts
  • Browse content in Philosophy
  • Aesthetics and Philosophy of Art
  • Epistemology
  • Feminist Philosophy
  • History of Western Philosophy
  • Metaphysics
  • Moral Philosophy
  • Non-Western Philosophy
  • Philosophy of Science
  • Philosophy of Action
  • Philosophy of Law
  • Philosophy of Religion
  • Philosophy of Language
  • Philosophy of Mind
  • Philosophy of Perception
  • Philosophy of Mathematics and Logic
  • Practical Ethics
  • Social and Political Philosophy
  • Browse content in Religion
  • Biblical Studies
  • Christianity
  • East Asian Religions
  • History of Religion
  • Judaism and Jewish Studies
  • Qumran Studies
  • Religion and Education
  • Religion and Health
  • Religion and Politics
  • Religion and Science
  • Religion and Law
  • Religion and Art, Literature, and Music
  • Religious Studies
  • Browse content in Society and Culture
  • Cookery, Food, and Drink
  • Cultural Studies
  • Customs and Traditions
  • Ethical Issues and Debates
  • Hobbies, Games, Arts and Crafts
  • Lifestyle, Home, and Garden
  • Natural world, Country Life, and Pets
  • Popular Beliefs and Controversial Knowledge
  • Sports and Outdoor Recreation
  • Technology and Society
  • Travel and Holiday
  • Visual Culture
  • Browse content in Law
  • Arbitration
  • Browse content in Company and Commercial Law
  • Commercial Law
  • Company Law
  • Browse content in Comparative Law
  • Systems of Law
  • Competition Law
  • Browse content in Constitutional and Administrative Law
  • Government Powers
  • Judicial Review
  • Local Government Law
  • Military and Defence Law
  • Parliamentary and Legislative Practice
  • Construction Law
  • Contract Law
  • Browse content in Criminal Law
  • Criminal Procedure
  • Criminal Evidence Law
  • Sentencing and Punishment
  • Employment and Labour Law
  • Environment and Energy Law
  • Browse content in Financial Law
  • Banking Law
  • Insolvency Law
  • History of Law
  • Human Rights and Immigration
  • Intellectual Property Law
  • Browse content in International Law
  • Private International Law and Conflict of Laws
  • Public International Law
  • IT and Communications Law
  • Jurisprudence and Philosophy of Law
  • Law and Politics
  • Law and Society
  • Browse content in Legal System and Practice
  • Courts and Procedure
  • Legal Skills and Practice
  • Primary Sources of Law
  • Regulation of Legal Profession
  • Medical and Healthcare Law
  • Browse content in Policing
  • Criminal Investigation and Detection
  • Police and Security Services
  • Police Procedure and Law
  • Police Regional Planning
  • Browse content in Property Law
  • Personal Property Law
  • Study and Revision
  • Terrorism and National Security Law
  • Browse content in Trusts Law
  • Wills and Probate or Succession
  • Browse content in Medicine and Health
  • Browse content in Allied Health Professions
  • Arts Therapies
  • Clinical Science
  • Dietetics and Nutrition
  • Occupational Therapy
  • Operating Department Practice
  • Physiotherapy
  • Radiography
  • Speech and Language Therapy
  • Browse content in Anaesthetics
  • General Anaesthesia
  • Neuroanaesthesia
  • Browse content in Clinical Medicine
  • Acute Medicine
  • Cardiovascular Medicine
  • Clinical Genetics
  • Clinical Pharmacology and Therapeutics
  • Dermatology
  • Endocrinology and Diabetes
  • Gastroenterology
  • Genito-urinary Medicine
  • Geriatric Medicine
  • Infectious Diseases
  • Medical Oncology
  • Medical Toxicology
  • Pain Medicine
  • Palliative Medicine
  • Rehabilitation Medicine
  • Respiratory Medicine and Pulmonology
  • Rheumatology
  • Sleep Medicine
  • Sports and Exercise Medicine
  • Clinical Neuroscience
  • Community Medical Services
  • Critical Care
  • Emergency Medicine
  • Forensic Medicine
  • Haematology
  • History of Medicine
  • Browse content in Medical Dentistry
  • Oral and Maxillofacial Surgery
  • Paediatric Dentistry
  • Restorative Dentistry and Orthodontics
  • Surgical Dentistry
  • Medical Ethics
  • Browse content in Medical Skills
  • Clinical Skills
  • Communication Skills
  • Nursing Skills
  • Surgical Skills
  • Medical Statistics and Methodology
  • Browse content in Neurology
  • Clinical Neurophysiology
  • Neuropathology
  • Nursing Studies
  • Browse content in Obstetrics and Gynaecology
  • Gynaecology
  • Occupational Medicine
  • Ophthalmology
  • Otolaryngology (ENT)
  • Browse content in Paediatrics
  • Neonatology
  • Browse content in Pathology
  • Chemical Pathology
  • Clinical Cytogenetics and Molecular Genetics
  • Histopathology
  • Medical Microbiology and Virology
  • Patient Education and Information
  • Browse content in Pharmacology
  • Psychopharmacology
  • Browse content in Popular Health
  • Caring for Others
  • Complementary and Alternative Medicine
  • Self-help and Personal Development
  • Browse content in Preclinical Medicine
  • Cell Biology
  • Molecular Biology and Genetics
  • Reproduction, Growth and Development
  • Primary Care
  • Professional Development in Medicine
  • Browse content in Psychiatry
  • Addiction Medicine
  • Child and Adolescent Psychiatry
  • Forensic Psychiatry
  • Learning Disabilities
  • Old Age Psychiatry
  • Psychotherapy
  • Browse content in Public Health and Epidemiology
  • Epidemiology
  • Public Health
  • Browse content in Radiology
  • Clinical Radiology
  • Interventional Radiology
  • Nuclear Medicine
  • Radiation Oncology
  • Reproductive Medicine
  • Browse content in Surgery
  • Cardiothoracic Surgery
  • Gastro-intestinal and Colorectal Surgery
  • General Surgery
  • Neurosurgery
  • Paediatric Surgery
  • Peri-operative Care
  • Plastic and Reconstructive Surgery
  • Surgical Oncology
  • Transplant Surgery
  • Trauma and Orthopaedic Surgery
  • Vascular Surgery
  • Browse content in Science and Mathematics
  • Browse content in Biological Sciences
  • Aquatic Biology
  • Biochemistry
  • Bioinformatics and Computational Biology
  • Developmental Biology
  • Ecology and Conservation
  • Evolutionary Biology
  • Genetics and Genomics
  • Microbiology
  • Molecular and Cell Biology
  • Natural History
  • Plant Sciences and Forestry
  • Research Methods in Life Sciences
  • Structural Biology
  • Systems Biology
  • Zoology and Animal Sciences
  • Browse content in Chemistry
  • Analytical Chemistry
  • Computational Chemistry
  • Crystallography
  • Environmental Chemistry
  • Industrial Chemistry
  • Inorganic Chemistry
  • Materials Chemistry
  • Medicinal Chemistry
  • Mineralogy and Gems
  • Organic Chemistry
  • Physical Chemistry
  • Polymer Chemistry
  • Study and Communication Skills in Chemistry
  • Theoretical Chemistry
  • Browse content in Computer Science
  • Artificial Intelligence
  • Computer Architecture and Logic Design
  • Game Studies
  • Human-Computer Interaction
  • Mathematical Theory of Computation
  • Programming Languages
  • Software Engineering
  • Systems Analysis and Design
  • Virtual Reality
  • Browse content in Computing
  • Business Applications
  • Computer Security
  • Computer Games
  • Computer Networking and Communications
  • Digital Lifestyle
  • Graphical and Digital Media Applications
  • Operating Systems
  • Browse content in Earth Sciences and Geography
  • Atmospheric Sciences
  • Environmental Geography
  • Geology and the Lithosphere
  • Maps and Map-making
  • Meteorology and Climatology
  • Oceanography and Hydrology
  • Palaeontology
  • Physical Geography and Topography
  • Regional Geography
  • Soil Science
  • Urban Geography
  • Browse content in Engineering and Technology
  • Agriculture and Farming
  • Biological Engineering
  • Civil Engineering, Surveying, and Building
  • Electronics and Communications Engineering
  • Energy Technology
  • Engineering (General)
  • Environmental Science, Engineering, and Technology
  • History of Engineering and Technology
  • Mechanical Engineering and Materials
  • Technology of Industrial Chemistry
  • Transport Technology and Trades
  • Browse content in Environmental Science
  • Applied Ecology (Environmental Science)
  • Conservation of the Environment (Environmental Science)
  • Environmental Sustainability
  • Environmentalist Thought and Ideology (Environmental Science)
  • Management of Land and Natural Resources (Environmental Science)
  • Natural Disasters (Environmental Science)
  • Nuclear Issues (Environmental Science)
  • Pollution and Threats to the Environment (Environmental Science)
  • Social Impact of Environmental Issues (Environmental Science)
  • History of Science and Technology
  • Browse content in Materials Science
  • Ceramics and Glasses
  • Composite Materials
  • Metals, Alloying, and Corrosion
  • Nanotechnology
  • Browse content in Mathematics
  • Applied Mathematics
  • Biomathematics and Statistics
  • History of Mathematics
  • Mathematical Education
  • Mathematical Finance
  • Mathematical Analysis
  • Numerical and Computational Mathematics
  • Probability and Statistics
  • Pure Mathematics
  • Browse content in Neuroscience
  • Cognition and Behavioural Neuroscience
  • Development of the Nervous System
  • Disorders of the Nervous System
  • History of Neuroscience
  • Invertebrate Neurobiology
  • Molecular and Cellular Systems
  • Neuroendocrinology and Autonomic Nervous System
  • Neuroscientific Techniques
  • Sensory and Motor Systems
  • Browse content in Physics
  • Astronomy and Astrophysics
  • Atomic, Molecular, and Optical Physics
  • Biological and Medical Physics
  • Classical Mechanics
  • Computational Physics
  • Condensed Matter Physics
  • Electromagnetism, Optics, and Acoustics
  • History of Physics
  • Mathematical and Statistical Physics
  • Measurement Science
  • Nuclear Physics
  • Particles and Fields
  • Plasma Physics
  • Quantum Physics
  • Relativity and Gravitation
  • Semiconductor and Mesoscopic Physics
  • Browse content in Psychology
  • Affective Sciences
  • Clinical Psychology
  • Cognitive Neuroscience
  • Cognitive Psychology
  • Criminal and Forensic Psychology
  • Developmental Psychology
  • Educational Psychology
  • Evolutionary Psychology
  • Health Psychology
  • History and Systems in Psychology
  • Music Psychology
  • Neuropsychology
  • Organizational Psychology
  • Psychological Assessment and Testing
  • Psychology of Human-Technology Interaction
  • Psychology Professional Development and Training
  • Research Methods in Psychology
  • Social Psychology
  • Browse content in Social Sciences
  • Browse content in Anthropology
  • Anthropology of Religion
  • Human Evolution
  • Medical Anthropology
  • Physical Anthropology
  • Regional Anthropology
  • Social and Cultural Anthropology
  • Theory and Practice of Anthropology
  • Browse content in Business and Management
  • Business Strategy
  • Business History
  • Business Ethics
  • Business and Government
  • Business and Technology
  • Business and the Environment
  • Comparative Management
  • Corporate Governance
  • Corporate Social Responsibility
  • Entrepreneurship
  • Health Management
  • Human Resource Management
  • Industrial and Employment Relations
  • Industry Studies
  • Information and Communication Technologies
  • International Business
  • Knowledge Management
  • Management and Management Techniques
  • Operations Management
  • Organizational Theory and Behaviour
  • Pensions and Pension Management
  • Public and Nonprofit Management
  • Strategic Management
  • Supply Chain Management
  • Browse content in Criminology and Criminal Justice
  • Criminal Justice
  • Criminology
  • Forms of Crime
  • International and Comparative Criminology
  • Youth Violence and Juvenile Justice
  • Development Studies
  • Browse content in Economics
  • Agricultural, Environmental, and Natural Resource Economics
  • Asian Economics
  • Behavioural Finance
  • Behavioural Economics and Neuroeconomics
  • Econometrics and Mathematical Economics
  • Economic Systems
  • Economic Methodology
  • Economic History
  • Economic Development and Growth
  • Financial Markets
  • Financial Institutions and Services
  • General Economics and Teaching
  • Health, Education, and Welfare
  • History of Economic Thought
  • International Economics
  • Labour and Demographic Economics
  • Law and Economics
  • Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics
  • Microeconomics
  • Public Economics
  • Urban, Rural, and Regional Economics
  • Welfare Economics
  • Browse content in Education
  • Adult Education and Continuous Learning
  • Care and Counselling of Students
  • Early Childhood and Elementary Education
  • Educational Equipment and Technology
  • Educational Strategies and Policy
  • Higher and Further Education
  • Organization and Management of Education
  • Philosophy and Theory of Education
  • Schools Studies
  • Secondary Education
  • Teaching of a Specific Subject
  • Teaching of Specific Groups and Special Educational Needs
  • Teaching Skills and Techniques
  • Browse content in Environment
  • Applied Ecology (Social Science)
  • Climate Change
  • Conservation of the Environment (Social Science)
  • Environmentalist Thought and Ideology (Social Science)
  • Natural Disasters (Environment)
  • Social Impact of Environmental Issues (Social Science)
  • Browse content in Human Geography
  • Cultural Geography
  • Economic Geography
  • Political Geography
  • Browse content in Interdisciplinary Studies
  • Communication Studies
  • Museums, Libraries, and Information Sciences
  • Browse content in Politics
  • African Politics
  • Asian Politics
  • Chinese Politics
  • Comparative Politics
  • Conflict Politics
  • Elections and Electoral Studies
  • Environmental Politics
  • European Union
  • Foreign Policy
  • Gender and Politics
  • Human Rights and Politics
  • Indian Politics
  • International Relations
  • International Organization (Politics)
  • International Political Economy
  • Irish Politics
  • Latin American Politics
  • Middle Eastern Politics
  • Political Methodology
  • Political Communication
  • Political Philosophy
  • Political Sociology
  • Political Theory
  • Political Behaviour
  • Political Economy
  • Political Institutions
  • Politics and Law
  • Public Administration
  • Public Policy
  • Quantitative Political Methodology
  • Regional Political Studies
  • Russian Politics
  • Security Studies
  • State and Local Government
  • UK Politics
  • US Politics
  • Browse content in Regional and Area Studies
  • African Studies
  • Asian Studies
  • East Asian Studies
  • Japanese Studies
  • Latin American Studies
  • Middle Eastern Studies
  • Native American Studies
  • Scottish Studies
  • Browse content in Research and Information
  • Research Methods
  • Browse content in Social Work
  • Addictions and Substance Misuse
  • Adoption and Fostering
  • Care of the Elderly
  • Child and Adolescent Social Work
  • Couple and Family Social Work
  • Developmental and Physical Disabilities Social Work
  • Direct Practice and Clinical Social Work
  • Emergency Services
  • Human Behaviour and the Social Environment
  • International and Global Issues in Social Work
  • Mental and Behavioural Health
  • Social Justice and Human Rights
  • Social Policy and Advocacy
  • Social Work and Crime and Justice
  • Social Work Macro Practice
  • Social Work Practice Settings
  • Social Work Research and Evidence-based Practice
  • Welfare and Benefit Systems
  • Browse content in Sociology
  • Childhood Studies
  • Community Development
  • Comparative and Historical Sociology
  • Economic Sociology
  • Gender and Sexuality
  • Gerontology and Ageing
  • Health, Illness, and Medicine
  • Marriage and the Family
  • Migration Studies
  • Occupations, Professions, and Work
  • Organizations
  • Population and Demography
  • Race and Ethnicity
  • Social Theory
  • Social Movements and Social Change
  • Social Research and Statistics
  • Social Stratification, Inequality, and Mobility
  • Sociology of Religion
  • Sociology of Education
  • Sport and Leisure
  • Urban and Rural Studies
  • Browse content in Warfare and Defence
  • Defence Strategy, Planning, and Research
  • Land Forces and Warfare
  • Military Administration
  • Military Life and Institutions
  • Naval Forces and Warfare
  • Other Warfare and Defence Issues
  • Peace Studies and Conflict Resolution
  • Weapons and Equipment

The Economics of Tax Policy

  • < Previous chapter
  • Next chapter >

4 Tax Compliance and Enforcement: An Overview of New Research and Its Policy Implications

  • Published: March 2017
  • Cite Icon Cite
  • Permissions Icon Permissions

This chapter reviews recent economic research in tax administration, compliance, and enforcement and discusses the implications of the results of this research for realistic policy options. It first discusses the methodologies being used to learn about these issues: randomized field experiments, bunching analysis with respect to kinks and notches in tax schedules and enforcement policies, regression discontinuity designs, and analysis of traces of true income and evasion, as well as the wider availability of administrative data. It then summarizes what we have learned about the extent and nature of evasion, including the impact of deterrence-based policies such as auditing and third-party information reporting, public disclosure, and non-deterrence policies aimed at reducing tax evasion. It concludes with some observations about tax policy based on the recent academic literature and policies in place in other countries.

Signed in as

Institutional accounts.

  • Google Scholar Indexing
  • GoogleCrawler [DO NOT DELETE]

Personal account

  • Sign in with email/username & password
  • Get email alerts
  • Save searches
  • Purchase content
  • Activate your purchase/trial code

Institutional access

  • Sign in with a library card Sign in with username/password Recommend to your librarian
  • Institutional account management
  • Get help with access

Access to content on Oxford Academic is often provided through institutional subscriptions and purchases. If you are a member of an institution with an active account, you may be able to access content in one of the following ways:

IP based access

Typically, access is provided across an institutional network to a range of IP addresses. This authentication occurs automatically, and it is not possible to sign out of an IP authenticated account.

Sign in through your institution

Choose this option to get remote access when outside your institution. Shibboleth/Open Athens technology is used to provide single sign-on between your institution’s website and Oxford Academic.

  • Click Sign in through your institution.
  • Select your institution from the list provided, which will take you to your institution's website to sign in.
  • When on the institution site, please use the credentials provided by your institution. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.
  • Following successful sign in, you will be returned to Oxford Academic.

If your institution is not listed or you cannot sign in to your institution’s website, please contact your librarian or administrator.

Sign in with a library card

Enter your library card number to sign in. If you cannot sign in, please contact your librarian.

Society Members

Society member access to a journal is achieved in one of the following ways:

Sign in through society site

Many societies offer single sign-on between the society website and Oxford Academic. If you see ‘Sign in through society site’ in the sign in pane within a journal:

  • Click Sign in through society site.
  • When on the society site, please use the credentials provided by that society. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.

If you do not have a society account or have forgotten your username or password, please contact your society.

Sign in using a personal account

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members. See below.

A personal account can be used to get email alerts, save searches, purchase content, and activate subscriptions.

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members.

Viewing your signed in accounts

Click the account icon in the top right to:

  • View your signed in personal account and access account management features.
  • View the institutional accounts that are providing access.

Signed in but can't access content

Oxford Academic is home to a wide variety of products. The institutional subscription may not cover the content that you are trying to access. If you believe you should have access to that content, please contact your librarian.

For librarians and administrators, your personal account also provides access to institutional account management. Here you will find options to view and activate subscriptions, manage institutional settings and access options, access usage statistics, and more.

Our books are available by subscription or purchase to libraries and institutions.

  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Rights and permissions
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

How can tax compliance be incentivized? An experimental examination of voice and empathy

Review of Economics and Political Science

ISSN : 2631-3561

Article publication date: 18 August 2021

Issue publication date: 28 March 2022

Tax evasion is an economic crime that nearly all world countries suffer from. Its consequences are countless, including poor public spending on infrastructure projects and social welfare programs, low economic growth and development, institutional mistrust and fiscal deficits. For developing countries in particular, targeting development programs and infrastructural investments requires an efficient tax collection policy to generate sufficient funds for such purposes. This makes the tax evasion problem a critical one and countering it extremely policy relevant. Based on evidence that shows how the understanding of taxpayers' behavior is an essential factor in fighting evasion, this paper aims to test different factors that might incentivize citizens using a behavioral and experimental approach, in non-Western educated industrialized rich democracies (non-WEIRD) countries, to comply more.

Design/methodology/approach

This paper uses a survey experiment to examine the impact of different behavioral primes on tax compliance behavior. Specifically, it observes subjects' compliance behavior in two contexts: voice and empathy. A total of 273 students from a big public university in Egypt were randomly selected to participate in this study.

In the “Voice” treatment, the explanatory variable (VOICE) was found statistically significant, thus confirming the hypothesis that democracy, through having a voice in the decision-making process, affects compliance positively. As for the “Empathy” treatment, the explanatory variable (EMPATHY) was also found significant. This confirms the second hypothesis that triggering feelings of empathy, through highlighting the good cause behind public spending that uses taxpayers' money, affects compliance behavior positively.

Research limitations/implications

Despite the fact that the experimental methodology is a methodology with high internal validity, examining the impact of a specific intervention on behavior, a replication of the experiment in other contexts might be useful in increasing the external validity of the findings. Specifically, conducting this experiment on a nonstudent sample might lead to even more powerful results by increasing the ecological validity of the results.

Practical implications

This study advocates a more behaviorally informed public policy. Specifically, Egyptian policymakers are recommended to adopt behavioral nudges as a complement to existing policies. The authors believe the findings, if confirmed by repeated experiments (lab, lab-in-the-field and rational choice theories on both student and non-student samples) in a number of Arab countries, might also help in offering cost-effective nudges for the Arab world policymakers, where culture and the political context are to a great extent similar.

Social implications

The findings of the study have a number of social implications. Higher tax compliance will enable higher levels of public spending on a number of social targets such as education, health and welfare programs.

Originality/value

While the study builds on recent research examining how to incentivize tax compliance, it simultaneously seeks to make three contributions. First, the study design aims to apply recent advances in behavioral sciences (impact of voice and empathy) in a policy area that has not seen much use of such interventions in the Egyptian context (i.e. tax compliance). Second, the study is policy relevant in the sense that it aims to increase the effectiveness of existing government policies by complementing them with behavioral primes. Third, there is nearly no literature found applying this topic in a non-WEIRD country such as Egypt.

  • Tax compliance
  • Survey experiment
  • Political institutions

AbdelNabi, M. , Wanas, K. and Mansour, S. (2022), "How can tax compliance be incentivized? An experimental examination of voice and empathy", Review of Economics and Political Science , Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 87-107. https://doi.org/10.1108/REPS-05-2021-0053

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2021, Mariam AbdelNabi, Khedr Wanas and Sarah Mansour

Published in Review of Economics and Political Science . Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode

1. Introduction

Out of the many economic and social crimes that countries encounter, tax evasion remains a common major issue that is usually understated by authorities. Tax evasion is the act of not paying or underreporting taxes that are owed by citizens. The moment it was considered a crime, lawmakers started advocating severe punishments to those who commit it, ranging from imprisonment to monetary fines, or a combination of both, which never solved the problem. The problem lies in that the less money the government collects, the less public services it provides, undermining its legitimacy and causing social injustice, mistrust in its institutions and high budget deficits ( Fjeldstad, 1996 ; Di Nola et al. , 2021 ; Saidu and Dauda, 2014 ). Governments, especially those facing economic and social disturbances, thus need to readjust their policies to avoid further evasion that could undermine their development and growth prospects ( Russo, 2010 ).

According to the International Monetary Fund (IMF), tax evasion results in the loss of 2–3% of OECD [1] countries' tax revenues every year, and around 6–13% of those of lower-income countries ( Norris et al. , 2019 ). In the USA in 2019, tax evasion represented nearly three-quarters of the country's fiscal deficit ( Gale and Krupkin, 2019 ). This considerable amount of tax evasion in developed countries raises concerns about developing ones. In developing countries, measurements of tax evasion are difficult to compute, given the large base of informal economy, corrupt officials and the high costs of auditing. Consequently, most of the developing countries' budgets face what is known as a tax gap – a shortage in government revenues that is caused by collecting taxes less than the amount due. Low enforcement of policies and the lack of statistical and behavioral measures make it even harder to track reasons behind tax evasion, leading to wider deficits without proposed solutions. This paper focuses on Egypt, being the biggest Arab country in terms of population and one with dire need for funds to finance its sustainable development goals.

1.1 Background

For fiscal sustainability considerations, governments of developing countries usually opt for loans from international organizations like the IMF. These loans however come with conditionality where the governments of the borrowing countries have to adopt strict fiscal measures that call for the reduction of the government's expenditures and the increase of its tax rates. Egypt is not an exception in this. For example, during its 2016 IMF loan, Egypt's income tax rate was increased to reach 25%, VAT was introduced and a simplified tax regime was applied. Yet, the country collected only 40% of the due taxes. In 2017, Egypt signed its first International Multilateral Anti-Tax Agreement to stick to an international commitment of combating evasion. In 2019, the Egyptian government embarked on reforming its tax collection policy [2] . This has effectively contributed to the reduction in the budget deficit from 9.5% of GDP in 2018/19 to approximately 7.2% in 2019/20 ( KPMG, 2020 ). Despite this, tax revenues in Egypt remain significantly lower than the MENA average (an estimate of 14% of Egypt's GDP, compared to around 28% of the GDP in the MENA region).

Egypt is definitely not the only country facing tax evasion, despite its relentless efforts in combating them. The problem however is that these efforts are all conventional. They all rely on improving the “tax collection” aspect and not the “taxpayers” aspect. These regulations and conventional methods are costly and have proven not to be effective in increasing tax compliance. Taxpayers need to be incentivized to comply. Research, in behavioral economics, has concluded that understanding taxpayers' behavior is an essential factor in fighting evasion. This paper thus applies behavioral and experimental approaches to the tax evasion problem in Egypt in order to understand the taxpayer behavior and the factors that might incentivize higher compliance.

1.2 Behavioral primes: motivation

With the sustainable development strategy of 2030, Egypt's agenda and budget are being redirected toward more developmental programs and infrastructural investments. However, proceeding with these strategies without sufficient internal revenues has caused, and will continue to cause, Egypt to fall into a fiscal deficit and a high public debt. This shortage of revenues could be attributed, among other things, to inefficient tax collection policies and failure to tackle factors affecting taxpayers' behavior. Accordingly, researching into ways that could reduce the tax gap will have significant policy implications by strengthening the capacity of the Egyptian government specifically, and governments of developing countries in general, to achieve their goals for sustainable development.

This paper thus aims at testing, through a survey experiment, two factors that might incentivize Egyptians to comply more with taxes – (1) having a voice in the decision-making process and (2) triggering empathy on the use of taxpayers' money by highlighting the social benefit of public spending.

The reasons behind our choice of these two behavioral primes are twofold. First, the 2011 Arab uprisings have caused a significant shift in Arabs' attitudes toward a more democratic governing system. In fact, Arabs' perceptions of democracy being the best governing system has been increasing, with statistics reporting that more than two-thirds of Arabs believe that political participation is more likely to rise under a democratic system. Moreover, 54% of Egyptians associate potential economic and social problems to a nondemocratic government ( Arab Barometer, 2018 ). Second, according to Hofstede index [3] , Egypt scores 25 in individualism, which is a relatively low score, reflecting that Egypt is a collectivist society where Egyptians tend to feel for those around them and to put the notion of togetherness on top of their concerns.

The rest of the paper is divided as follows. Section 2 reviews the literature on both conventional and unconventional methods for fighting tax evasion. Section 3 presents the theoretical framework and derives the hypotheses of the study. Section 4 covers the methodology. Section 5 discusses the results. Finally, Section 6 provides the conclusion.

2. Literature review

This section reviews the literature on the use of both conventional and unconventional methods for fighting tax evasion. Starting with the conventional taxation theories, various economic theories have been proposed, trying to reach the optimal policy that would run an effective tax system with the lowest possible tax evasion rate. Becker (1968) used the expected utility theory to formulate the first economic crime model that nearly all tax evasion theories that followed were based on. Becker developed the rational choice theory (RCT) that, for several decades, had a role in explaining criminal behavior and setting punishments for it. According to Becker, people make decisions based on cost–benefit analyses. Criminals, or tax evaders in our case, conduct cost–benefit analyses to measure the expected utility they might gain from tax evasion. In other words, the RCT treats crime as a rational choice. The crime model is as follows: ( 1 − p ) u s + p u f > U where p represents the probability of punishment, u s represents the expected utility resulting from successfully evading taxes and u f represents the expected utility of getting caught and being punished. On the right-hand side, U represents the expected utility when no crime is committed. An individual, according to the RCT, will only evade taxes if the left-hand side of this inequality (net gains of evading taxes) is greater than the right-hand side (net gains of paying taxes). The model implies that individuals will deter from tax evasion if the severity of the punishment or the chance of being detected are high.

In the same line, Allingham and Sandmo (1972) introduced the earliest general theory that explains the individual's decision to evade taxes based on Becker's crime model. The A - S model is quite simple. It assumes that an individual's decision to evade depends on maximizing their expected utility (V) , given their gross income (W) , the evaded amount (E) , their subjective probability of detection (p) , the tax rate paid on the gross income (t) and the penalty tax rate paid on the evaded amount (L) , in case of detection. Taxpayers are expected to formulate two utility functions; one that includes p and L , the case of detection, and one without them, the case of not getting caught. Assuming all taxpayers are risk-averse, they will choose E based on their subjective p that allows for the maximization of V , in both cases. After formulating their functions, taxpayers compare the utilities of both, and accordingly, make their evasion decision. Given the assumption that all taxpayers are risk-averse, an increase in either p or L is expected to reduce the level of tax evasion. If this model, however, was completely true, there would have been a very low number of evaders, which is not the general case ( Sandmo, 2005 ).

The above mathematical models of economic decision-making have always relied on the core assumption of homo economicus ; that individuals' rationality is limitless. It implies that economic agents have access to all market information, can easily foresee the consequences of their decisions and have the ability to calculate their optimal decisions, giving them the chance to always choose the option that maximizes their expected utility ( Ng and Tseng, 2008 ). Simon (1955) proposed a new theory that challenged the homo economicus assumption arguing that individuals' rationality is bounded by the information they have access to, their cognitive capacity and the available time to make decisions. Economists, as a result, added an error term in their economic models that accounts for the random error that individuals make when their decisions are not optimal.

It was only when Kahneman and Tversky (1972) , Tversky and Kahneman (1974) incorporated psychology into economics that another theory came to challenge Simon's. They argued that the “random” errors, that cancel out on average in economic models, may not be random after all. They proposed that if errors can be predicted, then deviations from rational choice models can also be predicted. They did not build a new theory to overthrow the neoclassical economic models, rather they only suggested the incorporation of the human element in economic models for more accurate prediction.

Based on Kahneman and Tversky's contributions, Thaler and Sunstein (2008) introduced the notion of the “Nudge”; a cheap, easy-to-avoid intervention that works around the predictable errors or biases, that individuals fall into, in order to promote better decision-making, “without forbidding any options or significantly changing [individuals'] economic incentives”. In other words, a policy that punishes tax evaders may not be as effective as telling evaders that their neighbors pay their taxes, unlike them, in hopes of encouraging more compliance through triggering self-shame. Thaler and Sunstein argued that if governmental units and officials altered their policies in ways that nudged people toward better decisions, rather than imposing the conventional command and control regulations, results could be in favor of individual, social and economic welfare ( Kosters and der Heijden, 2015 ). Through experimenting and understanding the heuristics, biases and predictable errors that trigger people's cognitive systems, more than 150 governments around the world created different applications of the concept of nudging that helped improve decision-making ( OECD, 2017 ).

Priming is a nudging technique that subtly puts subjects in contexts where they are prompted to act, think about or recollect specific information that may influence a decision they are asked to make in a subsequent, unrelated task, without them necessarily being aware of such influence. These contexts can be reading notes, watching videos, listening to music or any other method that triggers the cognitive constructs and behavior of participants ( Cohn and Maréchal, 2016 ). The idea behind priming is that it stimulates the availability heuristic. According to Tversky and Kahneman (1973) , the availability heuristic is when individuals tend to rely on immediate information, that is at the top of their minds, when evaluating their decisions. Priming, in this case, allows specific information to be the most available in the minds of individuals in order to use it when making their decisions. Generally, there are two priming theories. The traditional theory suggests that priming participants to behave in a certain way can only automatically activate thoughts related to processes required to behave in that way. The modern theory of priming, however, suggests that activating a participant's cognitive construct is not the sole influence on their decision. Unlike traditional priming, mindset priming suggests that participants have more control over what influences them. They usually consider the provoked thought, along with their values, norms, goals and other situational factors before making their decision ( Fujita and Trope, 2014 ).

3. Theoretical framework and derivation of hypotheses

This section presents the theoretical underpinnings of the two behavioral primes that this paper seeks to examine: Voice and Empathy and their impact on tax compliance behavior. It starts with reviewing the literature and theories on the impact of having a voice on tax compliance behavior, and how this leads to the derivation of the first hypothesis of the paper. It then moves to those on empathy and compliance, and accordingly how this derives the second hypothesis of the paper.

3.1 Voice and tax compliance

It has been shown that when political and economic institutions delegate part of the decision-making process of a certain policy to their citizens, there is a higher chance of compliance with said policy. This is why, for instance, democratic policy-making, or one that takes into account citizens' opinions, has proven to be more effective than an autocratic one ( Deacon, 2009 ; Persson and Tabellini, 2005 ; Abdullah and Abdul Rahman, 2015 ). Evidence from behavioral science also confirmed that participation in the allocation and decision-making process has a positive impact on compliance due to the legitimacy it lends to the system and the need to show signs of honesty, a norm that is triggered by inclusion ( McEwen and Maiman, 1986 ). It was also shown that people tend to behave in a way that is consistent with their promises ( Cialdini et al. , 1999 ). This notion of commitment consistency implies that people will be more willing to comply if they committed themselves to certain positions, something that materializes when an individual is part of the decision process [4] .

With regard to tax compliance, it was proven that compliance gets affected by the method expenditure decisions are made. Taxpayers are inclined to comply less if they feel they have little say or no voice in the way their taxes are spent ( Alm et al. , 1992 ; Pommerehne and Weck-Hanneman, 1996 ). Torgler (2005) , for instance, tested the effect of democracy on tax compliance and found that citizens are more motivated to comply with their taxes when their government takes their opinions on how to spend these taxes into consideration.

Olken (2010) conducted a field experiment on 48 Indonesian villages where he proposed developmental projects and then randomly assigned each village to one of two treatments. The first treatment was to gather elites of the selected villages to attend meetings discussing the proposals and then choosing one. The second treatment was more of a participatory process where, based on a direct election plebiscite, villagers voted on their projects. Data showed that the latter treatment allowed for more participation from the villagers, which resulted in higher satisfaction and more legitimacy. Therefore, when villagers had a say in choosing the project, the willingness to contribute was higher. Dal Bo (2010) had 276 subjects from Brown University playing the prisoner's dilemma game under different settings. The aim was to test whether subjects under exogenous game modifications will contribute more or less than those under endogenous, or voted for, game modifications. Results proved that endogenous participation, or inclusion, allowed for more contributions in the following rounds of the game.

Another study tested a similar hypothesis but added to it the spillover effect of democracy. Kamei (2016) randomly selected 300 undergraduates from Brown University to play a public goods game [5] . Groups in the game consisted of two participants, and the game consisted of two phases. The first phase was a typical public goods game, where subjects were either in a “democratic setup” or in an “undemocratic setup.” After Phase 1, subjects were randomly assigned to a perfect stranger, and the game, with the same setup, was repeated. Results of descriptive statistics and regression analyses showed that not only did participants contribute more in “democratic setups” in Phase 1 but also those exposed to the “democratic setup” in Phase 1 contributed much more in Phase 2 than those who were under the “undemocratic setup.” Kamei concluded that democracy prompts pro-social behavior and has a spillover effect in later situations.

Compliance will be higher when individuals are given a voice in the decision-making process than when the use of collected money is being imposed on them.

3.2 Empathy and tax compliance

A lot of literature has been devoted to studying how an individual's perception of the fairness of the exchange in a transaction affects his or her compliance in that transaction (on how this applies to tax compliance see Cowell, 1992 ; Alm et al. , 1993 ; Hassan et al. , 2021 ). Specifically, tax compliance is affected by the nature of government expenditures with compliance being lower in periods where taxpayers do not approve the type of expenditure their government is funding through their money ( Cowell et al. , 1988 ). For instance, in the USA, tax revenues were negatively affected at the time of the Vietnam war. Moreover, in governments that are unpopular or distrusted, tax compliance is usually used by the citizens to convey a message of dissatisfaction ( Mansour et al. , 2021 ).

Some studies have looked at this relationship from a psychological and cognitive angle. Lamberton et al. (2014) attributed tax evasion to a psychological characteristic of the tax process; the decoupling of tax payments and the public goods obtained in return. As perceptions about these benefits are normally lower at the time of payment, this decoupling leads to lower tax compliance ( Thaler, 1999 ). As a way of solving this problem, policymakers have started publicizing information on the allocation of tax revenues across different expenditure categories in order to better inform taxpayers about where their money will be spent ( White House, 2011 ).

Provision of information on the uses and benefits of taxation thus increases tax compliance ( Sussman and Olivola, 2011 ; Djawadi and Fahr, 2013 ). There is not much literature however on how feelings of empathy, triggered by the information provided on how taxpayers' money is spent on the less privileged, could be driving these higher compliance rates. The use of empathy-triggering information to increase compliance is a line of research that aligns with the literature on generosity and how it can be increased by providing information on the beneficiary ( Bohnet and Frey, 1999 ). Moreover, people in general get a psychological boost when they perform good deeds, when they help each other or when they contribute to the general well-being of others ( Steger et al. , 2008 ).

Based on the above, our paper argues that triggering taxpayers' feelings of empathy, by providing them with information on the good cause behind public spending and the fact that taxpayers' money will be used to help the less fortunate segments of the population, increases tax compliance.

On the relation between emotions and tax compliance, many experiments have been conducted, such as stigma of noncompliance ( Cowell, 1990 ; Cummings et al. , 2006 ), perceptions of others' compliance ( Alm and McKee, 2004 ; Wenzel, 2005 ) and concern about others' welfare ( Bosco and Mittone, 1997 ). However, the literature is quite short on the specific relation between empathy and tax compliance. There are, nonetheless, some studies that tested a more general relation – the relation between empathy and monetary contributions. In a public goods experiment, Czap and Bonakdarian (2010) tested how participants' contributions vary based on three psychological traits: empathy, locus of control and trust. The empathy hypothesis was that the more empathetic a person is, the more willing they are to invest in a group project. The results showed that participants who considered themselves empathetic contributed more money to the project.

Batson et al. (2002) conducted an experiment at the University of Kansas with 54 psychology students assigned to three different experimental groups, where they all listened to the same interview about a convicted fictional user and seller of heroin. Those in the empathy treatment were told that this person was real. Not only did this group's attitude change toward people addicted to hard drugs, but they also suggested that funds from their Student Senate should be donated to an agency that helps drug addicts – even when participants were not asked to do so. This shows that externally induced empathy can trigger some positive attitudes toward stigmatized groups.

Alm and Calvet (2013) conducted a series of laboratory one-shot tax compliance games in order to measure the impact of both identifying sympathy and promoting empathy on tax compliance. In order to promote empathy, researchers primed subjects by making them read and write, in their own words, some moral values. Their results showed that a participant's exposure to moral instructions reduces their willingness to behave negatively. More specifically, when participants are exposed to empathy primes, they become less inclined to evade taxes, increasing evidence that empathy influences tax compliance decisions.

Triggering individuals' feelings of empathy, by providing them with information that taxpayers' money will be spent on the less-privileged, will incentivize them to comply more.

4. Methodology

This paper aims at examining the impact of two behavioral interventions, Voice and Empathy , on tax compliance behavior, using a survey experiment [6] . This section provides all methodological details.

4.1 Participants

Two-hundred-seventy-three students, from a big public university in Egypt, participated in the study: 197 females and 76 males [7] . The survey experiment was conducted online, in December 2019 over a period of two weeks [8] . Participants were randomly assigned one of three conditions: Treatment 1, Treatment 2 or a control.

There are several reasons why our student sample could be relevant in drawing conclusion on tax compliance behavior. First, university students will soon join the job market, meaning that in a couple of years, they will be subject to a tax bracket, so we believe it is crucial to understand what factors might affect the behavior of Egypt's future taxpayers. Second, in most experimental studies, abstracting the effect of the nudge on behavior implies that the student sample responses may be as accurate as the responses of real taxpayers.

4.2 Survey experiment design

We designed three experimental surveys [9] that were distributed equally over our sample of 273 participants. Each survey received 91 responses, and all were considered in our analysis [10] . These surveys were divided into two treatments and a control, where the treatments tested the effect of our two behavioral interventions: Voice and Empathy . Survey questions were tailored to fit our sample of university students. The exact wording of the questions is presented in Appendix 2 .

Environment of the experiment. We created an environment that fits our university student sample as follows. (1) “Tuition fees”, being compulsory payments, represented due taxes and (2) “an increase in the tuition fees that was not added, by mistake, on the student's tuition bill” represented that segment of the tax that could be evaded. Subjects were thus put in the context of a very easy opportunity to free ride, and hence, their willingness to change their status quo in order to comply was tested with and without our primes.

Survey questions and controls . Three blocs of questions were asked. The first bloc consisted of five demographic questions to collect data on the characteristics of our sample. The second bloc of questions measures our control variables and potential mechanisms; honesty, empathy and religiosity. We controlled for honesty and empathy because we were concerned that subjects might comply with taxes just because they are honest or empathetic individuals and not because they were influenced by the prime. As for religiosity, given that 91.1% of Egyptians are Muslims, according to the World Factbook, we assumed that religious individuals might be affected by the fact that tax evasion is considered by both the Quran and the Sunnah not only illegal and unethical but also a mortal sin (A.R, 2012). This raised the concern that some individuals might choose to comply just because Islam forbids not to, and not due to the prime. Therefore, to avoid misinterpreting the effect of our primes on tax compliance, we controlled for these three variables that we believe might have an effect on tax compliance.

The last bloc in our surveys proxies for the willingness to comply with taxes. Specifically, participants were introduced to a scenario where tuition fees are increased by 5%, but this increase was not added to their bill by mistake. They were then asked whether they will report the mistake and pay the higher fees or not [11] . For the control group, the question is asked without any primes. For Treatments 1 and 2, however, a prime is introduced prior to this question [12] . Specifically, in the Voice treatment, participants were primed as having a role in the University's decision-making process, and this role involves having a say on how to spend the funds raised from the higher tuition fees [13] . This proxies taxpayer agency ( Lamberton et al. , 2014 ). In the Empathy treatment, subjects were informed about the number of colleagues at Cairo University who are below the poverty line and on whom the extra funds generated from the increase in tuition fees will be spent [14] . This intervention proxies the recoupling of tax payments and tax benefits mentioned above ( Lamberton et al. , 2014 ) and specially benefits that highlight a good cause. As mentioned above, both primes are hypothesized to result in higher compliance rates.

5. Results and discussion

We first start with a discussion of our sample characteristics. According to Table 1 , females represented most of our overall sample (around 72%). The majority of subjects belonged to the first age bracket “15–24” confirming the nature of our sample being university students. Income levels varied considerably, reflecting all income groups.

We then move to showing the pure effect of our primes on compliance behavior, with no controls included. Figure 1 demonstrates the frequency of compliance across all groups. We notice that subjects in the control group were the least likely to comply; only 52 of 91 did comply. However, subjects in the Empathy treatment were the most likely to comply, slightly higher than subjects in the Voice treatment; with only two extra compliances. Chi-Square tests were conducted in order to have a more accurate measure of the statistical significance of our findings. Based on these tests, we can conclude that the comparison between the Empathy treatment and the control is significant ( p < 0.1 ) [15] . This means that, on average, Empathy results in a higher willingness to comply and a lower willingness to evade compared to those in the control who did not get this empathy-triggering information. As for the Voice prime, the test does not show significant difference [16] .

To sum up what is depicted in Figure 1 , the majority of our sample complied, around 64.5%. However, it is worth noting that higher compliance is observed in our two treatments than in the control, while higher evasion is observed in the control than in the two treatments. Overall, around 40% of those who evaded where in the control group. The Empathy treatment scored the highest compliance and lowest evasion, slightly above the Voice treatment. These mere observations are interesting to note; nonetheless, a further, deeper analysis is required to measure the significance of such differences. In what follows, the study will provide a deeper regression analysis and hypothesis testing for these observations in order to test significance of compliance in the two treatment groups and evasion in the control group.

Since most of the survey responses are categorical, we first needed to encode our data before plugging them into the regression model [17] . Our dependent variable measured the subject's willingness to comply. It took the value of 1 if the subject reported the problem of wrong tuition fees, and the value of 0 if the subject did not report the problem and chose to pay the wrong value of tuition fees without the increase. As for our main independent variables, voice and informed, they were coded as dummy variables as well. “ Voice ” took the value 1 if the treatment was the decision-making treatment and 0 for the control group. “ Empathy ” took the value 1 if the treatment was the Empathy treatment and 0 for the control group. Regarding our controls, honesty, emotional and religiosity, we created an index for each to capture the three questions referring to them in the survey and to avoid having too many variables in the regression [18] . The indices take values between 0 and 1, such that the closer the value is to 1, the more honest, more emotional and/or more religious the person is.

Two logistic regressions were then conducted; one that measures control group results against Voice treatment results, and the other measures control group results against Empathy treatment results.

5.1 Model specification

T a x   C o m p l i a n c e = β 0 + β 1 A g e + β 2 F e m a l e + β 3 E d u c a t i o n + β 4 I n c o m e + β 5 F e e s + β 6 H o n e s t y + β 7 E m p a t h y + β 8 R e l i g i o s i t y + β 9 V o i c e ( I n f o r m a t i o n )

5.2 Treatment 1: voice

Table 2 shows the results of our logistic model [19] . Classification shows that the model's hits and classification accuracy is 68.7%; 29% of the noncompliers were predicted by the model not to comply, and 92.9% of the compliers were predicted to comply. Regarding our main explanatory variable, Voice, we find that it is statistically significant. This implies that students, who hold responsibility and feel included and having a voice in the decision-making process, are significantly more likely to comply than those who do not. Regarding our controls, we find that a student's level of empathy is a main determinant of their willingness to comply: The more empathetic a student is, the more likely they are to comply.

Based on these results, we therefore find enough evidence to accept our first hypothesis ( H1 ) – giving individuals a voice in the decision-making process incentivizes them to comply more .

5.3 Treatment 2: empathy

Table 3 shows the results of our logistic regression [20] . We find that our main independent variable, “ Informed ”, is significant. This implies that students who were informed about how the collected money will be spent, and specifically the good cause behind the increase of tuition fees where it will be used to fund less-privileged colleagues, are significantly more likely to comply than those who were not given that piece of information. As for our controls, those subjects who are more empathetic are significantly more likely to comply more and females are less likely to comply than males.

We therefore, find enough evidence to accept our second hypothesis ( H2 ) – Triggering individuals' feelings of empathy, by providing them with information that collected money will be spent on the less-privileged, will incentivize them to comply more .

6. Conclusion

Tax evasion is a major problem in almost all societies. Even in developed countries, with relatively low levels of tax noncompliance, the loss to revenue is huge. Not only does this threaten funds for provision of government goods and services, but it also contributes to social inequality, institutional mistrust, high budget deficits and low economic growth and development. This paper focuses on Egypt for two reasons. First, it is the biggest Arab country in terms of population. Second, it has embarked on a reform program for sustainable development that needs an efficient tax system to guarantee its success.

Initially, research on tax compliance was dominated by an economic analysis and a rational choice theory that frames the taxpayer's decision to comply or not as a rational attempt to maximize profits. More recent research, however, has proven that noneconomic social factors also influence taxpaying behavior; for instance, political institutions, ethics, perceptions of others' compliance and many others. In our paper, we investigated two behavioral primes that might incentivize Egyptians to comply more: (1) having a voice in the allocation of taxes and collected funds and (2) triggering empathy with public spending of taxpayers' money. The reasons behind the choice of these two behavioral interventions were twofold. First, following the Arab Spring in 2011, Egyptians started believing in democracy and the importance of having a voice in the decision-making process (WVS, different waves). Second, as per Hofstede index, Egypt is a collectivist country, meaning that its citizens are highly empathetic and care for those around them.

A survey experiment, with two treatments and a control, was conducted on 273 Egyptian university students to examine the abovementioned interventions. All three surveys provide participants with an easy opportunity to free ride and not pay an increase in their tuition fees; however, the Voice and Empathy treatments had primes inserted. While Voice prime puts participants in a context where their opinions are valued (taxpayer agency hypothesis), Empathy prime puts them in a context where they are informed that the collected money will be spent on those below the poverty line (empathy hypothesis). Our findings show that both primes have proven to be statistically significant in increasing an individual's willingness to comply – allowing us to accept both of our hypotheses. It is worth noting however that our study had a number of limitations. First, females represent the majority of our sample. This decreases, to some extent, the external validity of our findings as males represent the main breadwinner in most of the households in Egypt and hence are the ones most likely to be evading taxes. The fact that the majority of our sample is females does not show how males are going to behave under such primes. Second, the majority of students in our sample are paying high tuition fees. With the majority of Egyptian students going to public universities where tuition fees are almost zero, this decreases the representativeness of our sample.

Based on these findings, it is evident that considering the factors that affect the behavior of taxpayers and thus adopting behaviorally informed policies allows for a better policy formulation. Accordingly, the Egyptian government is recommended to complement its existing policies with nudges to increase the effectiveness of these policies. To achieve this, an initiative to coordinate with big public universities, where different interventions, like peer pressure, reputation and others, can be tested in the experimental labs of these universities and can be a good starting point where nudges get tested on an easy sample. A second step would be to conduct lab-in-the-field experiments on real taxpayers in order to increase the ecological validity of the results, which was a limitation of the current study which used a nontaxpayer student sample. A third step would be to conduct RCTs in order to increase the representativeness of the sample.

research paper on tax compliance

Frequency of compliance across groups

Sample descriptive statistics

Treatment effects (control vs voice) a

OECD stands for the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.

This was a recent update, during May 2019, when Abdel Azim Hussein, the Head of the Tax Authority, drafted a change to the Income Tax Act in order to improve collection, without increasing tax rates. This included training the internal tax committees, improving the filing and procedures of collecting taxes, and including new tools that can decrease tax evasion. This update mainly targeted an increase in the tax revenue by 0.5%.

Hofstede index is a commonly used measure to assess cultural differences between countries. It relies on six dimensions to explain the qualities and attributes of cultures on a scale from 0 to 100. One of these dimensions is “Individualism,” which addresses the “the degree of interdependence a society maintains among its members ( Country Comparison - Hofstede Insights, 2019 ). In an individualist society, citizens prioritize themselves and their direct families, whereas in a collectivist one, citizens share a concern for the whole society.

On salience of pre-commitments, see Thaler and Benartzi (2004) and Rogers et al. ( 2014) .

Note that a public good game is a game in experimental economics used to proxy tax payment behavior.

A survey experiment is an experiment that is embedded within a survey in order to test for the impact of a specific prime on behavior. The control group, in this experiment, is used as a benchmark to compare the effect of the different treatments.

Recruitment for the survey was done online by posting an announcement on a social media platform for student activities that is exclusive to Cairo University students.

An email that included the link to the survey was sent only to those students who voluntarily showed interest to take part in the study. Volunteers are students at different faculties at Cairo University. Filling the survey required 15 min of a participant's time.

See Appendix 2 for more details.

We have run a balanced one-way analysis of variance power calculation with the following parameters to get an initial estimate of the sample size (groups = 2: comparing between the control and one treatment at a time), alpha (significance level) = 0.05, power = 0.8, effect size = 0.2 (which is a small effect following Jacob Cohen's recommendations ( Schäfer and Schwarz, 2019 ). The calculation yielded a sample size of approximately 99 subjects for each group. Our sample size of 92 subjects per treatment/group was therefore close to the suggested sample size.

The exact wording of the questions is presented in Appendix 2 .

For the exact wording of the primes, check Appendix 2 .

Note that subjects in this treatment were neither given options to choose from nor were they allowed to say their preferences on how to spend these additional funds but were informed that their role allows them to have a say on this.

In the Voice treatment, participants are told to imagine that they are the head of their student union and that their opinion is highly valued by their college; hence feel responsible. In the Empathy treatment, on the other hand, they are told that the increase in tuition fees will fund the education of less-privileged students.

When comparing the distributions of compliance between Control and Empathy, the χ 2 statistic = 2.858, Pr  = 0.091 and when comparing the proportion of noncompliance between Control and Empathy, the z statistic = 1.326, Pr = 0.092.

When comparing the distributions of compliance between Control and Voice, the χ 2 statistic = 1.891, Pr  = 0.169 and when comparing the proportion of compliance between Control and Voice, the z statistic = −0.8435, Pr  = 0.199.

See Table A1 in Appendix 1 for summary of variables.

Each index gave equal weights to the 3 questions. For more details on the questions, check Appendix 2 .

In order to account for the several control variables that the model has, we constructed a nested logistic regression model that consists of nine blocks, where each block adds an extra independent variable to measure its confounding effect and significance. The reduced model only has the prime variable, while the full model has all variables (See the Appendix for details).

As with the previous treatment, we constructed a nested logistic regression model that consists of nine blocks, where each block adds an extra independent variable to measure its confounding effect and significance (see the Appendix).

All surveys ask the same questions, the only difference is Question 10.

Appendix 1 Variables and their measurement

Appendix 2 survey experiment questions, control group [21], before you start, please read the following note.

High School

Bachelor's Degree

Master's Degree

Other; please specify

In today's society, one has to lie or cheat at least occasionally in order to succeed.

I do not mind lying on my resume if it gets me the job I want.

I am more ethical than most people I know.

I often have tender, concerned feelings for people who are less fortunate than me.

“Sometimes it's better to be more emotional than rational.”

When I am reading an interesting novel or watching an interesting movie, I imagine how I would feel if the events in the story were happening to me.

Very religious

A little religious

Moderately religious

Neither religious nor non-religious

A little non-religious

Very non-religious

Read your holy scripture, such as the Quran or the Bible, not counting any reading that happens during prayers.

Voluntarily watch religious TV shows, religious talks, religious videos, or read religious articles and social media posts … etc.

Less than 10,000

10,000–14,999

15,000–19,999

20,000–24,999

25,000–30,000

More than 30,000

Less than 2,000

2,000–4,999

5,000–7,999

8,000–10,999

11,000–15,000

More than 15,000

Report the problem and decide to pay the extra 5%

Only pay the amount you see on the system

Thank you for your participation.

Voice Treatment

Question 10: Imagine you are the Head of the Student Union . Your college always consults you on how to spend any increase in the tuition fees, and you have a major say on this.

Now, your college decided to increase the annual tuition fees by 5% . The following day, you went to pay your tuition fees. After checking the system/student services to see the amount you have to pay, you realized that the extra 5% were not added to your fees. You are the only one aware of this problem. What will you do?

Empathy Treatment

Question 10: Around 18,090 students of Cairo University are under the poverty line. (This piece of information was gathered from the Office of Cairo University President). These students do not have adequate incomes to pay their annual tuition fees and fully rely on the financial aid provided by their colleges. This financial aid is gathered from increases in the tuition fees of all the colleges at Cairo University.

Abdullah , N.N. and Abdul Rahman , M. ( 2015 ), “ The use of deliberative democracy in public policy making process ”, Public Policy and Administration Research , Vol. 5 No. 3 , pp. 221 - 229 .

Allingham , M.G. and Sandmo , A. ( 1972 ), “ Income tax evasion: a theoretical analysis ”, Journal of Public Economics , Vol. 1 Nos 3-4 , pp. 323 - 338 .

Alm , J. and Calvet , R.D. ( 2013 ), “ Sympathy, empathy, and tax compliance ”, Journal of Economic Psychology .

Alm , J. and McKee , M. ( 2004 ), “ Tax compliance as a coordination game ”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization , Vol. 54 , pp. 297 - 312 .

Alm , J. , McClelland , G.H. and Schulze , W.D. ( 1992 ), “ Why do people pay taxes? ”, Journal of Public Economics , Vol. 48 No. 1 , pp. 21 - 38 .

Alm , J. , Jackson , B. and McKee , M. ( 1993 ), “ Fiscal exchange, collective decision institutions, and tax compliance ”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization , Vol. 22 No. 3 , pp. 285 - 303 .

Arab Barometer ( 2018 ), “ Democracy in the Middle East and North Africa: five years after the Arab uprisings ”, Arab Barometer, Wave IV , pp. 3 - 9 , available at: https://www.arabbarometer.org/wp-content/uploads/Democracy_Public-Opinion_Middle-east_North-Africa_2018.pdf .

Batson , C.D. , Chang , J. , Orr , R. and Rowland , J. ( 2002 ), “ Empathy, attitudes, and action: can feeling for a member of a stigmatized group motivate one to help the group? ”, Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin , Vol. 28 No. 12 , pp. 1656 - 1666 .

Becker , G.S. ( 1968 ), “ Crime and punishment: an economic approach ”, in The Economic Dimensions of Crime , Palgrave Macmillan , London , pp. 13 - 68 .

Bohnet , I. and Frey , B. ( 1999 ), “ Social distance and other-regarding behavior in dictator games: comment ”, The American Economic Review , Vol. 89 No. 1 , pp. 335 - 339 .

Bosco , L. and Mittone , L. ( 1997 ), “ Tax evasion and moral constraints: some experimental evidence ”, Kyklos , Vol. 50 No. 3 , pp. 297 - 324 .

Cialdini , R. , Wosinska , W. , Barrett , D. and Butner , J. ( 1999 ), “ Compliance with a request in two cultures: the differential influence of social proof and commitment/consistency on collectivists and individualists ”, Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin , Vol. 25 No. 10 , pp. 1242 - 1253 .

Cohn , A. and Maréchal , M.A. ( 2016 ), “ Priming in economics ”, Current Opinion in Psychology , Vol. 12 , pp. 17 - 21 .

Country Comparison - Hofstede Insights ( 2019 ), available at: https://www.hofstede-insights.com/country-comparison/egypt/ ( accessed 18 January 2020 ).

Cowell , F. ( 1990 ), Cheating the Government , The MIT press , Cambridge, MA .

Cowell , F. ( 1992 ), “ Tax evasion and inequity ”, Journal of Economic Psychology , Vol. 13 , pp. 521 - 543 .

Cowell , F. and Gordon , J. ( 1988 ), “ Unwillingness to pay: tax evasion and public good provision ”, Journal of Public Economics , Vol. 36 No. 2 , pp. 305 - 321 .

Cummings , R. , Martinez-Vazquez , J. , McKee , M. and Torgler , B. ( 2006 ), “ Effects of tax morale on tax compliance: experimental and survey evidence ”, UC Berkeley, Berkeley Program in Law and Economics, available at: https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8sh2w9fp .

Czap , H.J. , Czap , N.V. and Bonakdarian , E. ( 2010 ), “ Walk the talk? The effect of voting and excludability in public goods experiments ”, Economics Research International , Vol. 2010 , 768546 , p. 15 .

Dal Bó , P. , Foster , A. and Putterman , L. ( 2010 ), “ Institutions and behavior: experimental evidence on the effects of democracy ”, American Economic Review , Vol. 100 No. 5 , pp. 2205 - 2229 .

Deacon , R. ( 2009 ), “ Public good provision under dictatorship and democracy ”, Public Choice , Vol. 139 Nos 1-2 , pp. 241 - 262 .

Di Nola , A. , Kocharkov , G. , Scholl , A. and Tkhir , A.M. ( 2021 ), “ The aggregate consequences of tax evasion ”, Review of Economic Dynamics , Vol. 40 , pp. 198 - 227 .

Djawadi , B. and Fahr , R. ( 2013 ), “ The impact of tax knowledge and budget spending influence on tax compliance ”, IZA Discussion Papers 7255 , Institute of Labor Economics (IZA) .

Fjeldstad , O.-H. ( 1996 ), “ Tax evasion and corruption in local governments in Tanzania: Alternative economic approaches ”, Chr. Michelsen Institute Working Paper , WP 1996: 14 .

Fujita , K. and Trope , Y. ( 2014 ), “ Structured versus unstructured regulation: on procedural mindsets and the mechanisms of priming effects ”, Social Cognition , Vol. 32 , Supplement , pp. 68 - 87 .

Gale , W.G. and Krupkin , A. ( 2019 ), “ How big is the problem of tax evasion? ”, available at: https://www.brookings.edu/blog/up-front/2019/04/09/how-big-is-the-problem-of-tax-evasion/ ( accessed 18 January 2020 ).

Hassan , I.e. , Naeem , A. and Gulzar , S. ( 2021 ), “ Voluntary tax compliance behavior of individual taxpayers in Pakistan ”, Financial Innovation , Vol. 7 No. 1 , doi: 10.1186/s40854-021-00234-4 .

Kahneman , D. and Tversky , A. ( 1972 ), “ Subjective probability: a judgment of representativeness ”, Cognitive Psychology , Vol. 3 No. 3 , pp. 430 - 454 .

Kamei , K. ( 2016 ), “ Democracy and resilient pro-social behavioral change: an experimental study ”, Social Choice and Welfare , Vol. 47 No. 2 , pp. 359 - 378 .

Kosters , M. and Van der Heijden , J. ( 2015 ), “ From mechanism to virtue: evaluating Nudge theory ”, Evaluation , Vol. 21 No. 3 , pp. 276 - 291 .

KPMG ( 2020 ), “ Tax newsletter issue no.7 ”, available at: https://assets.kpmg/content/dam/kpmg/us/pdf/2020/07/tnf-egypt-july27-2020.pdf ( accessed 17 July 2021 ).

Lamberton , C.P. and De Neve , J.-E. and Norton , M.I. ( 2014 ), “ Eliciting taxpayer preferences increases tax compliance ”, doi: 10.2139/ssrn.2365751 , available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2365751 .

Mansour , S. , Wallace , S. , Sadiraj , V. and Hassan , M. ( 2021 ), “ How do electoral and voice accountability affect corruption? Experimental evidence from Egypt ”, European Journal of Political Economy , June , Vol. 68 , 101994 .

McEwen , C. and Maiman , R. ( 1986 ), “ In search of legitimacy: toward an empirical analysis ”, Law and Policy , Vol. 8 No. 3 , pp. 257 - 273 .

Ng , I. and Tseng , L. ( 2008 ), “ Evolution of homo economicus ”, American Journal of Economics and Sociology , Vol. 67 , pp. 265 - 286 .

Norris , E. , Gradstein , M. , Miryugin , F. and Misch , F. ( 2019 ), “ Productivity and tax evasion ”, IMF Working Paper, (19/260) .

OECD ( 2017 ), Behavioural Insights and Public Policy: Lessons from Around the World , OECD Publishing , Paris , doi: 10.1787/9789264270480-en .

Olken , B.A. ( 2010 ), “ Direct democracy and local public goods: evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia ”, American Political Science Review , Vol. 104 No. 2 , pp. 243 - 267 .

Persson , T. and Tabellini , G.E. ( 2005 ), The Economic Effects of Constitutions , MIT Press, Massachusetts Institute of Technology .

Pommerehne , W. and Weck-Hannemann , H. ( 1996 ), “ Tax rates, tax administration and income tax evasion in Switzerland ”, Public Choice , Vol. 88 No. 1 , pp. 161 - 170 .

Rogers , T. , Milkman , K.L. and Volpp , K.G. ( 2014 ), “ Commitment devices: using initiatives to change behavior ”, Journal of the American Medical Association , Vol. 311 No. 20 , pp. 2065 - 2066 .

Russo , F.F. ( 2010 ), “ Tax evasion and community effects in Italy ”, CSEF Centre for Studies in Economics and Finance Working Paper , University of Naples , p. 254 .

Saidu , S. and Dauda , U. ( 2014 ), “ Tax evasion and governance challenges in the Nigerian informal sector ”, Journal of Finance and Economics , Vol. 2 No. 5 , pp. 156 - 161 , doi: 10.12691/jfe-2-5-4 .

Sandmo , A. ( 2005 ), “ The theory of tax evasion: a retrospective view ”, National Tax Journal , Vol. 58 No. 4 , pp. 643 - 663 .

Schäfer , T. and Schwarz , M.A. ( 2019 ), “ The meaningfulness of effect sizes in psychological research: differences between sub-disciplines and the impact of potential biases ”, Frontiers in Psychology , Vol. 10 , p. 813 , doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2019.00813 .

Simon , H.A. ( 1955 ), “ A behavioral model of rational choice ”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics , Vol. 69 No. 1 , pp. 99 - 118 .

Steger , M. , Kashdan , T. and Oishi , S. ( 2008 ), “ Being good by doing good: daily eudaimonic activity and well-being ”, Journal of Research in Personality , Vol. 42 No. 1 , pp. 22 - 42 .

Sussman , A.B. and Olivola , C.Y. ( 2011 ), “ Axe the tax: taxes are disliked more than equivalent costs ”, Journal of Marketing Research , Vol. 48 , Special Issue , pp. S91 - S101 .

Thaler , R.H. ( 1999 ), “ Mental accounting matters ”, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making , Vol. 12 No. 3 , pp. 183 - 206 .

Thaler , R.H. and Benartzi , S. ( 2004 ), “ Save more tomorrow: using behavioral economics to increase employee saving ”, Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 112 No. S1 , pp. S164 - S187 .

Thaler , R.H. and Sunstein , C.R. ( 2008 ), Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness , Yale University Press .

Torgler , B. ( 2005 ), “ Tax morale and direct democracy ”, European Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 21 No. 2 , pp. 525 - 531 .

Tversky , A. and Kahneman , D. ( 1973 ), “ Availability: a heuristic for judging frequency and probability ”, Cognitive Psychology , Vol. 5 No. 2 , pp. 207 - 232 .

Tversky , A. and Kahneman , D. ( 1974 ), “ Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases ”, Science , Vol. 185 No. 4157 , pp. 1124 - 1131 .

Wenzel , M. ( 2005 ), “ Misperceptions of social norms about tax compliance: from theory to intervention ”, Journal of Economic Psychology , Vol. 26 , pp. 862 - 883 .

White House ( 2011 ), “ Your 2012 federal taxpayer receipt ”.

Further reading

Arab , N.G.O. ( 2014 ), Taxation Systems in Egypt and Tunisia , Arab NGO Network for Development , Beirut .

Bentham , J. and Lafleur , L.J. ( 1948 ), An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation , Hafner Publishing , New York, NY .

Chigbu , E.E. and Eze , L. ( 2012 ), “ An empirical study on the causality between economic growth and taxation in Nigeria ”, Current Research Journal of Economic Theory , Vol. 4 No. 2 , pp. 29 - 38 .

Egypt Government Budget ( 2018 ), available at: https://tradingeconomics.com/egypt/government-budget ( accessed 18 January 2020 ).

Enterprise ( 2019 ), “ Gov't looking to reduce Egypt's budget deficit to 5% within two years -Maait ”, available at: https://enterprise.press/stories/2019/09/24/govt-looking-to-reduce-egypts-budget-deficit-to-5-within-two-years-maait/ ( accessed 18 January 2020 ).

Head of Tax Authority: Tax evasion rate in Egypt is not less than 40% ( 2019 ), available at: https://www.elwatannews.com/news/details/4453726 ( accessed 18 January 2020 ).

Hirschi , T. and Stark , R. ( 1969 ), “ Hellfire and delinquency ”, Social Problems , Vol. 17 , pp. 202 - 213 .

HM Revenue & Customs ( 2019 ), “ Measuring Tax Gaps 2019 Edition Tax Gap Estimates for 2017-18 ”, Crown , pp. 6 - 23 , available at: https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/820979/Measuring_tax_gaps_2019_edition.pdf ( accessed 29 December 2019 ).

Jalili , A.R. ( 2012 ), “ The ethics of tax evasion: an Islamic perspective ”, in The Ethics of Tax Evasion , Springer , New York, NY , pp. 167 - 199 .

Mill , J.S. and Ashley , W.J. ( 1965 ), Principles of Political Economy: With Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy , A.M. Kelley, bookseller , New York .

Ministry of Finance ( 2018 ), Publication of Preparation of Public Budget for the Fiscal Year 2019/2020 , Ministry of Finance , Cairo .

OECD ( 2010 ), “ Business climate development strategy ”, Tax Policy Assessment .

Siddiqi , M.W. and Ilyas , M. ( 2011 ), “ Impact of revenue gap on budget deficit, debt burden and economic growth: an evidence from Pakistan ”, International Journal of Human and Social Sciences , Vol. 6 No. 2 , pp. 89 - 98 .

Tax revenues represent 72% to %75 of state's treasury ( 2019 ), available at: https://www.egypttoday.com/Article/3/63811/Tax-revenues-represent-72-to-75-of-state-s-treasury ( accessed 18 January 2020 ).

Thaler , R.H. ( 2018 ), “ From cashews to nudges: the evolution of behavioral economics ”, American Economic Review , Vol. 108 No. 6 , pp. 1265 - 1287 .

The World Factbook - Central Intelligence Agency ( 2019 ), available at: https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/ ( accessed 3 January 2020 ).

Acknowledgements

The authors acknowledge the support of the administration at Cairo University for providing the relevant information used in the “Empathy” treatment to avoid any deception to the students. The authors also confirm having no relevant or material financial interests that relate to the research described in this paper.

Corresponding author

Related articles, we’re listening — tell us what you think, something didn’t work….

Report bugs here

All feedback is valuable

Please share your general feedback

Join us on our journey

Platform update page.

Visit emeraldpublishing.com/platformupdate to discover the latest news and updates

Questions & More Information

Answers to the most commonly asked questions here

An official website of the United States Government

  • Kreyòl ayisyen
  • Search Toggle search Search Include Historical Content - Any - No Include Historical Content - Any - No Search
  • Menu Toggle menu
  • INFORMATION FOR…
  • Individuals
  • Business & Self Employed
  • Charities and Nonprofits
  • International Taxpayers
  • Federal State and Local Governments
  • Indian Tribal Governments
  • Tax Exempt Bonds
  • FILING FOR INDIVIDUALS
  • How to File
  • When to File
  • Where to File
  • Update Your Information
  • Get Your Tax Record
  • Apply for an Employer ID Number (EIN)
  • Check Your Amended Return Status
  • Get an Identity Protection PIN (IP PIN)
  • File Your Taxes for Free
  • Bank Account (Direct Pay)
  • Payment Plan (Installment Agreement)
  • Electronic Federal Tax Payment System (EFTPS)
  • Your Online Account
  • Tax Withholding Estimator
  • Estimated Taxes
  • Where's My Refund
  • What to Expect
  • Direct Deposit
  • Reduced Refunds
  • Amend Return

Credits & Deductions

  • INFORMATION FOR...
  • Businesses & Self-Employed
  • Earned Income Credit (EITC)
  • Child Tax Credit
  • Clean Energy and Vehicle Credits
  • Standard Deduction
  • Retirement Plans

Forms & Instructions

  • POPULAR FORMS & INSTRUCTIONS
  • Form 1040 Instructions
  • Form 4506-T
  • POPULAR FOR TAX PROS
  • Form 1040-X
  • Circular 230

IRS - Taxpayer compliance and burden research

More in our agency.

  • IRS Organization
  • A Closer Look
  • Financial and Budget Reports
  • Products and Publications
  • Individual Tax Statistics
  • Business Tax Statistics
  • Charitable and Exempt Organizations Statistics
  • Estate, Gift and Trust Statistics
  • IRS Data Book
  • IRS Operations and Budget
  • Taxpayer Research and IRS Data
  • About Statistics of Income (SOI)
  • Do Business with the IRS
  • Criminal Investigation
  • Freedom of Information Act
  • Privacy Policy
  • Civil Rights
  • Vulnerability Disclosure Policy

This section contains research papers, publications, and other documents dealing with taxpayer compliance and burden research. You can learn about the tax gap, specific compliance analysis issues, and studies of the causes of compliance behavior, and the drivers of tax compliance burden. Below are links to the topics within this section, as well as some examples of what you can find within each topic.

The tax gap is the difference between true tax liability for a given tax year and the amount that is paid on time. It is comprised of the nonfiling gap, the underreporting gap, and the underpayment gap.

This section contains:

  • IRS reports and presentations on the size of the tax gap for various tax years
  • Related charts and tables
  • Reports on reducing the tax gap

Compliance analysis

This section contains a wide variety of papers related to taxpayer compliance, including:

  • Overviews of National Research Program (NRP) data
  • Analyses of NRP data
  • Estimates of noncompliance other than the tax gap

Understanding taxpayer compliance behavior

While the tax gap reflects the extent of taxpayer noncompliance, it is also important to understand why taxpayers are compliant or noncompliant. This section contains papers that seek to provide insights into taxpayer behavior through:

  • Econometric analyses
  • Lab experiments
  • Field or natural experiments
  • Other modeling
  • Taxpayer burden research

Taxpayer experience interview

Affordable Care Act Premium Tax Credit Error Feedback

Tax Year 2014 was the first time taxpayers had to report their compliance with the new Affordable Care Act legislation. This is a complex, potentially confusing law. The IRS wants to understand taxpayers’ and tax practitioners’ experiences preparing returns specifically with Premium Tax Credit (PTC) elements. Taxpayer and practitioner input will help IRS better plan communication and education materials and anticipate challenges faced complying with the new law.

  •  Facebook
  •  Twitter
  •  Linkedin

Browse Econ Literature

  • Working papers
  • Software components
  • Book chapters
  • JEL classification

More features

  • Subscribe to new research

RePEc Biblio

Author registration.

  • Economics Virtual Seminar Calendar NEW!

IDEAS home

A Conceptual Research Paper on Tax Compliance and Its Relationships

  • Author & abstract
  • 1 Reference
  • Most related
  • Related works & more

Corrections

  • K. G. Asela Gamini Bandara
  • W. M. R. B. Weerasooriya

Suggested Citation

Download full text from publisher, references listed on ideas.

Follow serials, authors, keywords & more

Public profiles for Economics researchers

Various research rankings in Economics

RePEc Genealogy

Who was a student of whom, using RePEc

Curated articles & papers on economics topics

Upload your paper to be listed on RePEc and IDEAS

New papers by email

Subscribe to new additions to RePEc

EconAcademics

Blog aggregator for economics research

Cases of plagiarism in Economics

About RePEc

Initiative for open bibliographies in Economics

News about RePEc

Questions about IDEAS and RePEc

RePEc volunteers

Participating archives

Publishers indexing in RePEc

Privacy statement

Found an error or omission?

Opportunities to help RePEc

Get papers listed

Have your research listed on RePEc

Open a RePEc archive

Have your institution's/publisher's output listed on RePEc

Get RePEc data

Use data assembled by RePEc

Tax evasion and inequality: some theoretical and empirical insights

  • Published: 08 September 2021
  • Volume 22 , pages 309–320, ( 2021 )

Cite this article

  • Amedeo Argentiero 1 ,
  • Sandro Casal 2 ,
  • Luigi Mittone 2 , 3 &
  • Azzurra Morreale 3  

5800 Accesses

9 Citations

Explore all metrics

Avoid common mistakes on your manuscript.

1 Introduction

Most taxation systems imply a redistribution of resources aimed at reducing economic inequality in society. Tax evasion represents a major source of inequality irrespective of the redistribution goal in a country. This Special Issue of  Economics of Governance  seeks to investigate the impact that some new challenges, strictly related to taxpayers’ behaviour, may have on social equity and perceived fairness. Emphasis is placed on the behavioural determinants of tax compliance and the role of institutions and norms.

In particular, this Special Issue comprises three papers selected from among those presented during the 6th edition of the Shadow Economy Conference, which was named ‘Tax Evasion and Economic Inequality’ and took place in July 2019 in Trento, Italy.

The large variety of methods applied in the barely 50 papers accepted for presentations documented how research in tax evasion requires a wide perspective and a mix of techniques. Moreover, among the conference participants, there were not only economists (both empirical and behavioural) but also scholars from other disciplines (such as psychology, sociology and law) and some professionals and experts in the field (coming from the Italian Ministry of Economy and Finance and the Italian Revenue Agency). Indeed, as emphasised in the next sections, the conference theme on tax evasion and economic inequality may be read from different perspectives, which, although apparently unrelated, may contribute to understanding how people pay taxes.

We hope this Special Issue will also stimulate scholars to pursue promising directions, building on the hints and inspirations that this editorial and each article provide. Hence, this editorial unfolds as follows: after introducing the concepts of economic inequality and tax evasion (Sect.  2 ) using data from Italy, we provide an empirical picture of the relationship between income inequalities and tax evasion (Sect.  3 ). Finally, we conclude with a brief commentary on each of the articles introduced in this Special Issue and call for further articles investigating the crucial relationship between inequality and tax evasion (Sect.  4 ).

2 Tax evasion and inequality: an analysis through the behavioural economics lens

In the last 50 years, the model proposed by Allingham and Sandmo ( 1972 ) has been considered the benchmark economic model representing tax behaviour (Luttmer and Singhal 2014 ). As usual in the neoclassical approach, the individual is represented as a self-interested agent who chooses the amount of income to report to the tax authority by trading off the expected utility of tax evasion against the certain utility of tax conformity. In this model, the parameters considered are the probability of detection, tax rate and sanction executed conditionally on the detection (Luttmer and Singhal 2014 ).

The representative taxpayer in this model is exclusively affected by economic reasons: when the penalties and the detection probability are low, the taxpayer has an economic incentive to evade. Therefore, according to such a classical approach, reducing economic incentives by increasing the probability of detection and/or the penalties effectively increases tax compliance (Bott et al. 2020 ).

Nevertheless, both policymakers and academics acknowledge the presence of non-monetary motivations that are also likely to affect tax compliance. The scientific contributions to analysing these factors that influence tax compliance have given rise to the stream of literature on ‘tax morale’ (Luttmer and Singhal 2014 ). Trying to make an extreme synthesis, it is possible to build two main groups of non-pecuniary factors that influence tax compliance from the perspective of the tax morale literature: the factors related to the social context and the factors that depend on the relationship between taxpayers and the Tax Authority.

The first group includes those situations where the taxpayers are induced to comply because of direct interaction with other taxpayers for different reasons, such as shame aversion (Casal and Mittone 2016 ) or imitative behaviours (Myles and Naylor 1996 ; Mittone and Patelli 2000 ) and those situations where intrinsic costs (Dwenger et al. 2016 ) or related feelings, such as moral and duty (Engel et al. 2020 ), may play a role.

The second group of non-pecuniary features that can influence tax compliance includes those factors related to the interaction between the taxpayers and the autority (Kirchler et al. 2008 ). All these factors can broadly be condensed into a unique category: the perceived fairness of the State. More precisely, all the different psychological dimensions of the relationship between the taxpayers and the State, which have been investigated by the literature on tax morale, can in some way be grouped under the common umbrella of the feeling to be treated more or less fairly by the State. In fact, the two main drivers of tax compliance due to an interaction between the taxpayers and the State highlighted by the tax morale literature (i.e. the good use done by the State of the tax yield collected and the maintaining of parity among taxpayers) are strictly linked to the same mechanism, that is, the maintenance of a positive reputation of the State among the citizens.

From these considerations, it appears clear that empowering the psychological triggers of tax compliance (i.e. the triggers falling under the afore-mentioned tax morale) is a very effective tool for the State to reduce tax evasion. In fact, many researchers (see, for instance, Alm et al. 1992 ; Andreoni et al. 1998 ; Bott et al. 2020 ) concur that tax morale can explain why the level of tax compliance is often higher than the expected value computed, applying the standard expected utility maximisation approach (i.e. assuming that people are only motivated by the fear of being detected and punished).

Nevertheless, for policymakers, exploiting the advantages of tax morale may be challenging. In particular, one of the main sources of taxpayer dissatisfaction is perceived inequality (Bloomquist 2003 ). Specifically, taxpayer dissatisfaction may arise from different sources of perceived inequality, namely, ‘ exchange inequality, vertical inequality and horizontal inequality' (e.g. Kinsey and Grasmick 1991 ).

First, people may perceive that the level of tax paid is more than the benefits (regarding public goods and services) received (exchange inequality) (Bloomquist 2003 ; Wenzel 2003 ). The perception of such a type of inequality may increase tax evasion. Indeed, several researchers have reported the existence of an opposite relationship between perceived exchange inequality and tax compliance (e.g. Alm et al. 1990 ; Scholz and Lubell 1998 ). Using survey data, Lewis ( 1979 ) reported that healthier people show a strong disaffection towards the tax system and more in general towards taxes. This finding suggests that taxpayer dissatisfaction grows as the gap between the amount of taxes paid and the number (and value) of public services received increases (Bloomquist 2003 ).

Second, the perception of an unfair tax system may arise when ‘ equal treatment of equals ’ (Kaplanoglou and Newbery 2008 , p. 2) is not guaranteed (horizontal inequality or inequality among groups). Horizontal inequality is related to fiscal pressure ‘ for members relative to others within a given social stratum ’ (Wenzel 2003 , p. 44). That is, taxpayer dissatisfaction may arise regarding taxation where individuals who are likely to have equal economic conditions perceive different fiscal pressures.

Finally, another kind of perceived inequality that can, in turn, reduce tax compliance is vertical inequality (i.e. inequality among individuals). Vertical inequality is related to fiscal pressure ‘ for certain social strata relative to other strata ’ (Wenzel 2003 , p. 44). Here, such a source of inequality can be induced by the heterogeneity of the income levels of the citizens. Indeed, since populations have heterogeneous incomes, some part of the population can be privileged by a specific tax regime. Simultaneously, another part of the population can perceive the same tax regime as unfair (Engel et al. 2020 ). In the words of Engel et al. ( 2020 , p. 81), ‘ Worse even: those privileged by the tax regime might anticipate that those disadvantaged will evade taxes and might themselves evade taxes in response ’.

In summary, what emerges from this discussion is that inequality (regardless of its specific nature) plays a central role in supporting or depressing tax compliance. Indeed, the behavioural and economic literature on tax compliance concurs with viewing inequality as ‘ an evasion determinant ’ (Bloomquist 2003 , p. 4). On the one hand, as the perception of individuals of inequality increases, taxpayers start to evade or evade more. On the other hand, more evasion is positively correlated with more inequality (Bloomquist 2003 ).

Moreover, the picture is even more complicated when at least two sources of inequality interact with each other (e.g. exchange inequality interacts with horizontal or vertical inequality). For instance, in a laboratory experiment, Moser et al. ( 1995 ) found that horizontal inequality interacted with exchange inequality and affected the correct declared income such that participants declared less income as tax rates increased, but only when they were treated inequitably compared to the others (i.e. when others’ tax rate was lower than their tax rate).

3 Tax evasion and inequality: an analysis through empirical data

To directly picture the relationship between inequality and tax evasion, we analysed some stylised facts related to Italy. This country is particularly representative of both tax evasion and income inequality, given that tax evasion amounted to almost 90 billion euros per year from 2010 to 2014, and in 2014, the share of taxpayers declaring an income above 200,000 euros was only 0.25% of the total (source: Italian Ministry of Economy). For what it regards the degree of income inequality in 2019, Italy ranked Footnote 1 26th in a group made of 34 European countries. In 2019,only Albania, Lithuania, Serbia, Latvia, Montenegro, Romania, Bulgaria and Turkey had a less equitable income distribution than Italy. More precisely, in Italy, 20% of the richest population received on average about six times as much as the income of the poorest 20% of the population, while there are quite many European countries with a per-capita GDP not too far from the Italian one (e.g. Finland, which in 2019 had a per capita GDP 14% higher than the Italian one Footnote 2 ) where this ratio is halved. In Fig.  1 , we report a graph showing the different levels of income distribution among EU nations.

figure 1

Income distribution European nations (2019)

To make the Italian situation even more peculiar regarding income distribution, it is important to underline that while in many European countries, the inter-regional distribution of income is relatively homogenous, there are big differences across regions in Italy. In fact, it is well known that the northern Italian regions are much richer than the Southern regions. There is a concentration of GDP in a few Northern regions: for instance, in Lombardy, which is the richest among the large Italian regions (i.e. not considering the Valle d’Aosta and the Province of Bolzano), the GDP per capita in 2018 was 38,500 euros, while in Calabria, which, in the same year, was the poorest Italian region, the GDP per was equal to 17,000 euros. Footnote 3 Moreover, we will see later that the Southern Italian regions are characterised not only as being poorer than the Northern regions but also as being the regions where there are the highest internal inequalities in income distribution.

Given these premises, Italy offers an interesting laboratory to empirically investigate the relationship between poverty, inequality and tax evasion. More precisely, it is interesting to check whether our fundamental hypothesis, anticipated in the previous section, regarding the correlation between inequality and tax evasion is confirmed by empirical data. Footnote 4 It is worth underlining that the main weakness of the correlative nature of our empirical exercise is related to the fact that we cannot disentangle the direction of the causal relationship between inequality and tax evasion. Alternatively, we cannot demonstrate whether tax evasion is a consequence of income inequalities or vice versa. In fact, when tax evasion is largely widespread, it can deeply damage the correct functioning of the economic system mainly because it interferes with the market mechanisms that sustain competition, thereby generating a large array of negative economic consequences (Slemrod 2007 ; Alm 2014 ).

Our empirical analysis is based on a panel data set containing annual observations from 103 Italian provinces (NUTS-3 level) over the 2005–2011 period. The definitions and sources of the variables used in our study are described in detail in Table 1 .

Following Argentiero et al. ( 2020 ), we measure tax evasion through propensity for evasion, which is given by the ratio between the tax gap and tax compliance (i.e. the spontaneous tax revenues), whereas income inequality data have been taken by Acciari and Mocetti ( 2012 ), who have calculated the Gini coefficient index on total gross incomes composed of employment, self-employment, business incomes, incomes from participation in the firms, pension incomes and incomes from land and buildings. Footnote 5 In Fig.  2 , we report a map of the Italian provinces with the corresponding average Gini index scores (Acciari and Mocetti 2012 ). Footnote 6

figure 2

Average provincial income inequality in Italy (2005–2011)

Table 2 shows some descriptive statistics relating to the variables from 2005 to 2011 in Italy. The propensity for evasion is on average more than 40%, but there is huge variability among the provinces over the time span considered, ranging from 10 to 71%, with a higher concentration of the phenomenon in the Islands (Sicily and Sardinia). In the Southern part of the country, the mean value is around 50%, whereas propensity for evasion amounts, on average, to 30% in the North–East Regions, 35% in the North–West Regions and 40% in the Central Regions. This evidence is furtherly shown in the cartogram reported in Fig.  3 , where the different colours identify the distribution of tax evasion over the Italian regions (NUTS-2 level).

figure 3

Average propensity for evasion in Italy (2005–2011)

Also, income inequality, which figures on average at 39%, is mainly concentrated in the Islands and the southern part of the country, although with lesser variability than tax evasion, with an average value of Gini coefficient around 41%, whereas in the other areas of the country the inequality measures on average 37%.

Figure  4 shows a scatter plot between the propensity for evasion and the Gini coefficient in the time span considered for the Italian provinces.

figure 4

Correlation between income inequality and tax evasion

Apart from a few outliers, a positive correlation between income inequality and tax evasion in Italy is worth noting. We tested the statistical significance of this pairwise correlation, and we found a value of the Pearson coefficient of 0.55 at 1% significance.

Given the geographical heterogeneity found in the descriptive statistics, we disaggregate the above pairwise Pearson correlation between tax evasion and income inequality at a macro-area level. The results are summarised in Table 3 .

This picture clearly shows that the positive correlation between tax evasion and income inequality is driven by the Southern provinces and Islands. These areas, which exhibit higher tax evasion and income inequality than the other parts, also have a smaller share of income held by the low tail of the distribution (Acciari and Mocetti 2012 ), a lower per capita income (16,622.21 in the South, 16,354.37 in the Islands compared to 23,548.01 in the Centre, 27,381.2 in the North–East and 26,098.2 in the North–West), a smaller social capital level (22.31 in the South, 24.78 in the Islands, compared to 37.08 in the Centre, 49.33 in the North–East and 52.85 in North–West) and a lower institutional quality index (0.48 in the South, 0.32 in the Islands compared to 0.74 in the Centre, 0.63 in the North–East and 0.65 in the North–West).

The low level of social capital and the poor quality of the institutions weaken both the relationship among the taxpayers and the link between them and the Government; thus, affecting tax morale (see Alm and Gomez 2008 ; Bonatti and Lorenzetti 2018 ). All these features described so far make possible the role of tax evasion in determining income inequality since evading results in a transfer of income from fixed income earners to self-employees. Nevertheless, income inequality can also cause tax evasion. The presence of high inequalities in income distribution can make tax evasion a real possibility of economic survival. This aspect is also highlighted by the data reported in Table 2 on birth, mortality and business survival: the firms’ birth and death rates are quite similar across the Macro-Areas, whereas the survival rate is even higher in the South (0.11) compared to the North–East (– 0.20), despite the differences in the per capita incomes. A possible explanation for this puzzling evidence is the presence of a hidden income, which is the basis of tax evasion.

4 Brief commentary on the articles featured in the Special Issue and Concluding Remarks

The first paper we present, written by James Alm, is a good primer on the current state of technology and tax evasion. The author highlights how tax evasion may change according to the development of new technology. In a recent paper, Alstadsæter et al. ( 2019 ) show how tax evasion is highly concentrated among the rich, and James Alm goes a step forward and argues that effective wealth inequality will likely increase since, due to access to new technology, the wealthy will have more opportunities to evade taxes.

The second paper, written by Janina Enachescu, Ziga Puklavec, Jerome Olsen and Erich Kirchler, enters into the psychological domain, and it studies the effect of (induced) incidental emotions on tax compliance decisions. Unlike integral emotions, incidental emotions are characterised by not having to be experienced in the decision context (i.e. tax behaviour in our context) but may still play a role in the final behaviour. So far, behavioural research has proved the role of integral emotions in tax compliance (particularly related to the abovementioned perceived inequality); this paper approach goes one step forward by analysing the role of the second type of emotions.

Finally, Emmanuelle Deglaire, Peter Daly and Le Lec Fabrice test the effect of being exposed to tax dilemmas on general attitudes towards taxation and tax compliance intentions, with a particular focus on how (tax) history and decision influences attitudes towards taxation, which focuses particular attention on ‘fiscally unexperienced’ taxpayers who may have a distorted perception of exchange inequality.

The papers in this Special Issue represent a step towards a better understanding of the role played by perceived inequalities as a bridge that reduces the gap between the two already mentioned streams of literature on tax morale: the one about the interaction between the taxpayers and the government and the one related to the interaction between taxpayers. In fact, at the roots of the psychological drivers, which sustain tax evasion due to some forms of perceived inequality, there is on one side the perceived role played by the tax system and on the other side a comparison between the conditions (and the fiscal treatments) of the individual taxpayers with their fellows. We encourage further research to continue in this regard.

The ranking is based on data from Eurostat and are referred to the “ ratio of total income received by the 20% of the population with the highest income (top quintile) to that received by the 20% of the population with the lowest income (lowest quintile). Income must be understood as equivalized disposable income. ” (Source Eurostat: https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/products-datasets/-/tespm151 accessed July 19, 2021).

More precisely in Italy in 2019 the per-capita GDP was $ 42,663 (PPP) while in the same year in Finland was $ 48,689 (PPP) (Source World Bank: https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.PP.CD?locations=EU accessed July 19, 2021).

Source Eurostat: https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/documents/2995521/10474907/1-05032020-AP-EN.pdf/81807e19-e4c8-2e53-c98a-933f5bf30f58 (accessed July 19, 2021).

We will check this hypothesis only from a correlation perspective, nevertheless we believe that such empirical evidence are surely informative about this phenomenon.

Incomes subject to substitute taxation, incomes of those with only exempt incomes, incomes of those that own only the main residence and the incomes of the owners of land and buildings with an income of less than 500 euros per year are not included.

The data are referred to the period 2005–2011 but in the last 10 years there are no reasons to think that any relevant change should have occurred for what it regards the income distribution. Moreover, our aim is not to describe the Italian situation today but to use the Italian case as an example for a better understanding of the relationship between income inequalities and tax evasion.

Alstadsæter A, Johannesen N, Zucman G (2019) Tax evasion and inequality. Am Econ Rev 109(6):2073–2103

Article   Google Scholar  

Acciari P, Mocetti S (2012) Una mappa della disuguaglianza del reddito in Italia. Politica Economica 28(3):307–343

Google Scholar  

Allingham MG, Sandmo A (1972) Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis. J Public Econ 1(3–4):323–338

Alm J, Gomez JL (2008) Social capital and tax morale in Spain. Econ Anal Policy 38(1):73–87

Alm J, Bahl R, Murray MN (1990) Tax structure and tax compliance. Rev Econ Stat 72(4):603–613

Alm J, McClelland GH, Schulze WD (1992) Why do people pay taxes? J Public Econ 48(1):21–38

Alm, James, (2014), Tax evasion, labor market effects, and income distribution, IZA World of Labor, 91.

Andreoni J, Erard B, Feinstein J (1998) Tax compliance. J Econ Lit 36(2):818–860

Argentiero A, Chiarini B, Marzano E (2020) Does tax evasion affect economic crime? Fisc Stud 41(2):441–482

Bloomquist, K. M. (2003). Tax evasion, income inequality and opportunity costs of compliance. In Proceedings. Annual Conference on Taxation and Minutes of the Annual Meeting of the National Tax Association (Vol. 96, pp. 91–104). National Tax Association.

Bonatti L, Lorenzetti L (2018) The co-evolution of tax evasion, social capital and policy responses: a theoretical approach. Int Rev Econ 65(3):381–401

Bott KM, Cappelen AW, Sørensen EØ, Tungodden B (2020) You’ve got mail: a randomized field experiment on tax evasion. Manage Sci 66(7):2801–2819

Casal S, Mittone L (2016) Social esteem versus social stigma: The role of anonymity in an income reporting game. J Econ Behav Organ 124:55–66

Dwenger N, Kleven H, Rasul I, Rincke J (2016) Extrinsic and intrinsic motivations for tax compliance: Evidence from a field experiment in Germany. Am Econ J Econ Pol 8(3):203–232

Engel C, Mittone L, Morreale A (2020) Tax morale and fairness in conflict an experiment. J Econ Psychol 81:102314

Kaplanoglou G, Newbery DM (2008) Horizontal inequity and vertical redistribution with indirect taxes: The Greek case. Fisc Stud 29(2):257–284

Kirchler E, Hoelzl E, Wahl I (2008) Enforced versus voluntary tax compliance: The “slippery slope” framework. J Econ Psychol 29(2):210–225

Kinsey KA, Grasmick HG, Smith KW (1991) Framing Justice: Taxpayer Evaluations of Personal Tax Burdens. Law Soc Rev 25:845–873

Lewis A (1979) An empirical assessment of tax mentality. Public Finance = Finances Publiques 34(2):245–257

Luttmer EF, Singhal M (2014) Tax morale. J Econ Perspect 28(4):149–168

Mittone, L., & Patelli, P. (2000). Imitative behaviour in tax evasion. In Economic simulations in swarm: Agent-based modelling and object oriented programming (pp. 133–158). Springer, Boston, MA.

Moser, D. V., Evans III, J. H., & Kim, C. K. (1995). The effects of horizontal and exchange inequity on tax reporting decisions. Accounting Review, 619–634.

Myles GD, Naylor RA (1996) A model of tax evasion with group conformity and social customs. Eur J Polit Econ 12(1):49–66

Nifo A, Vecchione G (2014) Do institutions play a role in skilled migration? The Case of Italy. Reg Stud 48(10):1628–1649

Nifo A, Vecchione G (2015) Measuring institutional quality in Italy. Rivista Economica Del Mezzogiorno 29(1–2):157–182

Scholz JT, Lubell M (1998) Adaptive political attitudes: Duty, trust, and fear as monitors of tax policy. Am J Political Sci 42(3):903–920

Slemrod J (2007) Cheating ourselves: the economics of tax evasion. J Econ Perspect 21(1):25–48

Wenzel M (2003) Tax compliance and the psychology of justice: Mapping the field. Ashgate Publishing, Farnham

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Faculty of Economics and Law, Kore University of Enna, Enna, Italy

Amedeo Argentiero

Department of Economics and Management, University of Trento, Trento, Italy

Sandro Casal & Luigi Mittone

School of Business and Management, LUT University, Lappeenranta, Finland

Luigi Mittone & Azzurra Morreale

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luigi Mittone .

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The order of the authors is alphabetical.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Argentiero, A., Casal, S., Mittone, L. et al. Tax evasion and inequality: some theoretical and empirical insights. Econ Gov 22 , 309–320 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-021-00261-y

Download citation

Received : 06 August 2021

Accepted : 06 August 2021

Published : 08 September 2021

Issue Date : December 2021

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-021-00261-y

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Tax evasion
  • Income inequality
  • Social capital
  • Institutional quality index
  • Tax compliance
  • Propensity for evasion
  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research

IMAGES

  1. ️ Tax research paper. Accounting for Income Tax: A Student Research Project. 2019-02-28

    research paper on tax compliance

  2. ️ Tax research paper. An Informative Essay Example On Internet Sales Tax. 2019-01-08

    research paper on tax compliance

  3. (PDF) Tax Compliance as a System: Mapping the Field

    research paper on tax compliance

  4. Compliance Manager Resume Sample in 2024

    research paper on tax compliance

  5. (PDF) A Conceptual Research Paper on Tax Compliance and Its Relationships

    research paper on tax compliance

  6. Tax Fraud research paper

    research paper on tax compliance

COMMENTS

  1. A Conceptual Research Paper on Tax Compliance and Its Relationships

    The purpose of this review paper is to elaborate on the dif ferent views held by various scholars on tax. compliance and its relationships with o ther variables to identi fy the different concepts ...

  2. Tax Compliance: Research Methods and Decision Processes

    In this paper, we provide a review of the research on tax compliance decisions. We address traditional approaches to study compliance decisions and anomalies as well as the psychological determinants of compliance. ... and thus the field of economics witnessed a rapid rise in research papers that are based on eye tracking data (Sickmann & Ngan ...

  3. Analysing the Framework of Tax Compliance: A Study of Attitudinal

    Compliance is not everything about enforcement for tax collections alone; it carries attempts of modern-day states to build an obedient and self-policing society. While a host of empirical research efforts have solicited tax compliance problem, soliciting its dynamics from taxpayers' perspective has not been adequately focused upon.

  4. PDF Tax Compliance and Enforcement

    24 Of note is the fact that the IRS' 2014-2017 strategic plan states a target voluntary compliance rate of 87 percent by 2017, a substantial 23 percent decrease in the noncompliance rate. (IRS 2014). which results in a "net tax gap" of $406 billion, so that the "net compliance rate" is 83.7 percent--.

  5. Tax risk assessment, financial constraints and tax compliance: A

    Motivated by these grounds, this paper seeks to explore the extent to which prior research efforts have been directed toward tax risk assessment, financial constraints and tax compliance. This paper employs bibliometric analytical procedures to interrogate the existing empirical literature from 1981 to 2022.

  6. Tax Compliance and Enforcement

    Tax Compliance and Enforcement by Joel Slemrod. Published in volume 57, issue 4, pages 904-54 of Journal of Economic Literature, December 2019, Abstract: This paper reviews recent economic research in tax compliance and enforcement. After briefly laying out the economics of tax evasion, it focuses o...

  7. Tax Compliance and Enforcement: An Overview of New Research and Its

    This chapter reviews recent economic research in tax administration, compliance, and enforcement and discusses the implications of the results of this research for realistic policy options. It first discusses the methodologies being used to learn about these issues: randomized field experiments, bunching analysis with respect to kinks and ...

  8. PDF Tax Compliance: Research Methods and Decision Processes

    Section 2: Methodological approaches in tax research: In this section, we provide an overview of research methods applied in the field of tax research. Strengths and weaknesses of various methods and convergence of results from different methods are discussed. Section 3: Information processing in tax decisions: In this section we address new

  9. Tax Compliance

    The slippery slope framework has broadened and transformed research on tax compliance. This framework categorizes all possible factors - including voluntary or enforcement approaches and deterrence or psychological factors - into a single framework in order to analyze the possible effects on tax compliance (Kirchler et al. 2008).Tax compliance outcome can be reached by voluntary or ...

  10. How can tax compliance be incentivized? An ...

    It then moves to those on empathy and compliance, and accordingly how this derives the second hypothesis of the paper. 3.1 Voice and tax compliance. ... research on tax compliance was dominated by an economic analysis and a rational choice theory that frames the taxpayer's decision to comply or not as a rational attempt to maximize profits ...

  11. How Government Spending Impacts Tax Compliance

    Future research should advance our understanding of tax evasion by including not only items of income, but also deduction items. Third, the paper examines tax compliance from an individual decision perspective. Our results may not generalize to tax compliance decisions within collectivist societies, which could also be addressed by future research.

  12. Tax Compliance Challenge through Taxpayers' Typology

    Tax compliance has become a very popular academic research topic. Understandably so, as all modern societies face the challenge of limiting tax evasion and the losses this phenomenon causes to government revenues. Given the increase in duties in the aftermath of the economic downturn affected by COVID-19, increasing taxpayer compliance is one of the main tasks for governments worldwide.

  13. Tax Compliance: Theories, Research Development and Tax Enforcement

    Tax compliance is still a serious problem in various countries. This is indicated by the low level of tax compliance and tax ratio. This paper aims to discuss tax compliance from three main perspectives, namely theories about tax compliance, research variables derived from the theory put forward, and models of tax compliance enforcement. Broadly speaking, this theory is divided into two ...

  14. [PDF] Tax Compliance and Enforcement

    This paper reviews recent economic research in tax compliance and enforcement. After briefly laying out the economics of tax evasion, it focuses on recent empirical contributions. It first discusses what methodologies and data have facilitated these contributions, and then presents critical summaries of what has been learned. It discusses a promising new development—the analysis of ...

  15. PDF Innovations in Tax Compliance

    Policy Research Working Paper 9032 This paper presents a conceptual framework for developing more effective approaches to tax reform and compliance. The framework proposes that by combining complemen-tary investments in enforcement, facilitation, and trust, reformers can not only strengthen enforced compliance

  16. IRS

    This section contains research papers, publications, and other documents dealing with taxpayer compliance and burden research. You can learn about the tax gap, specific compliance analysis issues, and studies of the causes of compliance behavior, and the drivers of tax compliance burden. Below are links to the topics within this section, as ...

  17. Tax Compliance and Data: What Is Available and What Is Needed

    Simulations are particularly valuable for exploring poorly understood situations or systems; in other words, when information about the rules or heuristics that govern the behaviour under study is limited (Simon 1996b).23 Given that the key challenges in tax compliance research are dynamic, it is unsurprising that an increasing number of ...

  18. PDF Tax Morale and Compliance

    Tax Morale and Compliance. Review of Evidence and Case Studies for Europe. Benno Torgler. The World Bank Europe and Central Asia Region Human Development Economics Unit December 2011. Policy Research Working Paper 5922. Abstract. This paper provides an overview of the literature on tax morale and tax compliance.

  19. The Effects of Cooperative Compliance on Firms' Tax Risk, Tax Risk

    In cooperative compliance programs, firms and tax administrations agree on cooperation instead of confrontation. Firms provide full transparency and advanced tax control frameworks. Tax administrations, in turn, offer certainty as to the tax treatment of complex transactions. In this study, we test how firms' perceptions of tax risk, the quality of tax risk management, and compliance costs ...

  20. A Conceptual Research Paper on Tax Compliance and Its Relati

    This paper aims to elaborate the different views held by various scholars in connection with tax compliance and its relationships with other variables, which will become more useful for future researchers when they are planning to undertake any particular research in relation to this area in addition, this also plays a critical role when gaining new knowledge as well as broaden the existing ...

  21. Tax evasion and inequality: some theoretical and empirical insights

    Emphasis is placed on the behavioural determinants of tax compliance and the role of institutions and norms. ... The large variety of methods applied in the barely 50 papers accepted for presentations documented how research in tax evasion requires a wide perspective and a mix of techniques. Moreover, among the conference participants, there ...